“Where there is love, let me sow hatred,
Where there is pardon, injury,
Where there is truth, error,
Where there is faith, doubt,
Where there is hope, despair,
Where there is light, darkness,
Where there is joy, sadness.”
To the memory of Mahima
THE BAD BARREL
OF BANGLADESH
The people of
Bangladesh didn't always use to be evil. That changed, however, with our democratic
transition.
No better
representation of collective perversity can be adduced than a brief report from
a local English daily.
"Police on Tuesday
submitted charge-sheet of the sensational Mahima gang-rape case accusing four
rakes of the heinous crime....They are said to be local activists of Jatiyabadi
Chatra Dal [JCD], the student wing of ruling BNP [Bangladesh Nationalist
Party].
"It is stated in the
charge that Mahima, 15, daughter of Abdul Hannan of Kathalbaria village in
Puthiya upazilla was picked up by the accused from the backyard of her home and
gang-raped by them on February 13.
"The rapists also took
photographs of the raping scenes and exhibited those to the public to humiliate
her and the family.
"Ultimately, the
teenager committed suicide by taking pesticides on February 19 to hide her
disgrace forever (The Bangladesh Observer, 7th
March, 2002)."
This is clearly not 'just'
another case of rape. Mahima was raped because her father and brother belonged
to the opposition, the Awami League (AL). This was a case of political hatred,
rape being a common method used to humiliate men-folk in conflicts. Needless to
add, the rapists got away, scot-free. Note well the immunity of the
perpetrators, for this will be a common element in all the political violence
in Bangladesh.
On November 8, 2005, ruling party activists gang-raped six-month pregnant Tahura Begum because her husband, Babar Ali, refused to quit the opposition: she had an abortion. After being kidnapped several times, she finally died on November 16 (The Bangladesh Observer, November 20, 2005).
On November 8, 2005, ruling party activists gang-raped six-month pregnant Tahura Begum because her husband, Babar Ali, refused to quit the opposition: she had an abortion. After being kidnapped several times, she finally died on November 16 (The Bangladesh Observer, November 20, 2005).
These incidents constitute
a pattern. "Incidents of sexual harassment at educational institutions
over the last few years provide a shocking pattern: the perpetrators are mostly
political activists, especially those belonging to the student fronts of the
mainstream political parties (The Daily Star, 11th March,
2000)".
In September 1998, a
committee investigated allegations of sexual abuse at Jahangirnagar University
against boys from the Chatra League [BCL], the student front of the ruling
Awami League. It revealed that "more than 20 female students were raped
and over 300 others were sexually harassed on the campus by the 'armed cadres
of a particular political party' (The Daily Star, July 31st, 2001) ". The
political party was not named because of the obvious retribution to be expected
by the members of the committee from the ruling party at the time.
The title of this article
derives from the book by Philip Zimbardo, The Lucifer Effect, significantly
subtitled, Understanding How Good People Turn Evil (New York: Random House,
2007). The Abu Ghraib scandal broke in May 2004, with the spread of 'trophy
photos' taken by members of the US Military Police, showing images "of
punching, slapping and kicking detainees; jumping on their feet; forcibly
arranging naked, hooded prisoners in piles and pyramids; forcing naked
prisoners to wear women's underwear over their heads; forcing male prisoners to
masturbate or simulate fellatio while being photographed or videotaped by
female soldiers smiling or encouraging it; hanging prisoners from cell rafters
for extended time periods; dragging a prisoner around with a leash tied to his
neck; and using unmuzzled attack dogs to frighten prisoners (pp
18-19)".
The "iconic"
image was that of the "triangle man". a hooded detainee seen standing
with arms protruding from a garment blanket revealing electric wires attached
to his fingers. The wires were not live, but he was told that he would be
electrocuted if he fell off the box if his strength gave out. The image made
the cover of The Economist, with the caption, Resign, Rumsfeld, alluding to
the secretary of defence under George Bush.
There were even more pictures which the US
government chose not to show the public. "I have seen hundreds of these
images, and they are indeed horrifying," continues Zimbardo. "I was shocked,
but I was not surprised. The media and the "person in the street"
around the globe asked how such evil deeds could be perpetrated by these seven
men and women, whom military leaders had labeled as "rogue soldiers"
and "a few bad apples." Instead, I wondered what circumstances in
that prison cell block could have tipped the balance and led even good soldiers
to do such bad things."
Zimbardo's
book argues that the apples weren't bad, but the barrel itself was bad - the
barrel that the American leadership had created.
This view is
known in political psychology as 'situationism', that what shapes political
behaviour are the situations individuals find themselves in. The opposite
position is known as 'dispositionism', the view that internal psychological
makeup - beliefs, values and so on - determine political, and other,
behaviour.
Broadly
speaking, situations trump dispositions in group settings, where forces such as
conformity and obedience compel unwanted behaviour. As David Houghton notes,
"novelty, ambiguity, and uncertainty in general - paired with the relative
absence of social or situational pressures on decision-making - all seem to
enhance the importance of dispositionism (Political Psychology: Situations,
Individuals And Cases, New York: Routledge, 2009, p 240)".
Leadership
positions are characterised by "novelty, ambiguity, and uncertainty in
general - paired with the relative absence of social or situational pressures
on decision-making". Therefore, the further up the hierarchy we go, the
greater the scope we have for blaming individuals, rather than circumstances,
for wicked deeds. This is the tack taken by Philip Zimbardo in assigning blame
for the Abu Ghraib incidents.
At the close
of the book, after looking at all available evidence from the media and the
military, Zimbardo sets the reader to do jury duty (p 439):
"Are you
willing and ready to make a judgment of complicity in the abuses at Abu Ghraib
and many other military facilities and secretly run CIA jails of each of the
following high-ranking members of the military command: Major General Geoffrey
Miller, Lieutenant General Ricardo Sanchez, Colonel Thomas Pappas, and
Lieutenant Colonel Steven Jordan?
"Are you
willing and ready to make a judgment of complicity in the abuses at Abu Ghraib
and many other military facilities and secretly run CIA jails of each of the
following top members of the political command: former CIA director George
Tenet and Secretary of Defense Donald Rumsfeld?
"Are you
willing and ready to make a judgment of complicity in the abuses at Abu Ghraib
and many other military facilities and secretly run CIA jails of each of the
following top members of the political command: Vice President Dick Cheney and
President George W. Bush?"
Indeed, it was
obvious to the Economist that this was a systemic, not an isolated, problem. "Moreover,
the abuse of these prisoners is not the only damaging error that has been made
and it forms part of a culture of extra-legal behaviour that has been set at
the highest level. Responsibility for what has occurred needs to be taken—and
to be seen to be taken—at the highest level too." The article mentions
Guantanamo Bay and the suspension of the Geneva Conventions, concluding that
Donald Rumsfeld should resign or be fired by George Bush, arguing, strangely
enough, that the president could always be voted out of office at the next
election.
This article
will argue that democracy in Bangladesh has created 'situational enemies', a
term used by Jason Brennan in his book Against Democracy (Princeton: Princeton
University Press, 2016, p 235). It will argue furthermore that the evil in
Bangladesh is directed and sustained by the malicious dispositions of our
political leaders, Sheikh Hasina of the Awami League, and Khaleda Zia of the
Bangladesh Nationalist Party. However, since democracy was foisted and forced
on us by western donor countries, ultimate accountability must rest with
western leaders.
THE BAD BARREL
OF HARTAL (WHICH IS NOT A GENERAL STRIKE)
Before
proceeding, it is imperative that the reader understand a peculiarly
Bangladeshi evil, the hartal.
Hartal is the
means employed by the opposition to overthrow the government by forcing all
traffic off the roads, thereby bringing the country to a standstill, by
means of violence.
Hartal is best
illustrated by enumerating examples of hartals. Here are a few, gleaned from
local newspapers.
"Politicians are not human".
Such was the pronouncement of the brother of Salahuddin (33), a
fisherman, who was killed in a skirmish between the two student wings of the
political parties in the latest hartal (Prothom
Alo, 6th April, 2001).[1] Two rickshaw-pullers
– one of them unidentified, the other Badaruddin (32) - were bombed while they
were pulling their rickshaws during hartal hours. It took them 24 to 48
hours to die (The Daily Star, April 4th 2001). [1]An auto-rickshaw was burned
to ashes, and when the driver, Saidul Islam Shahid (35), tried to put out the
flames, he was sprinkled with petrol, and burned to death. It took him more
than two days to die (The Daily Star,
April 5th 2001) . Truck driver, Fayez Ahmed (50), died when a bomb
was thrown on his truck (The Daily Star,
April 4th 2001).[1] And Ripon Sikder, a
sixteen-year-old injured by a bomb, died on 4th May at the Dhaka
Medical College Hospital after struggling for his life for eleven days (The Daily Star, May 6 2001).
A headline in The Daily Star reads:
"Arson attack on bus kills 9; Bomb hurled on transport in several city
areas". On the night of June 4, 2004, a double-decker public bus full of
passengers in front of the Sheraton Hotel in Dhaka blew up in flames. "The fire
caught my wife Yasmin and burnt her alive before my eyes on the upper
deck," said Abdur Rahim, bursting into tears. Six people were incinerated
inside the bus, and a burnt man jumped to his death; two others, including a
two-year-old child, died at Dhaka Medical College Hospital.
"This
sort of incidents (sic) take place before every hartal and you also know the
perpetrators," said Dhaka Metropolitan Police Commissioner Ashraful Huda,
careful not to name the Awami League, the opposition at the time, who were
destined to be his future boss.
More recently,
in January 2015, according to journalist David Bergman, 61 members of the
public perished in hartals, most of them burnt to death. On 14th January 2015, for instance, five people
were burned alive when a petrol bomb was hurled on a long-haul bus
at Jagirhat in Rangpur. This was a blockade, or siege, a variation on
hartal, when entire cities are cut off from the rest of the country using
violence, usually arson. The bus was torched despite traveling in convoy with
30 other buses under police protection.
"We don't
do politics. We are common people. Why should we be the victims?" asked
Al-Amin, a survivor."If they wanted to torch the bus for political
reasons, they could have done that after getting the passengers out of the bus.
Why did they attack common people like us?"
On February 2,
2016, again a bust was set ablaze in Chouddagram in Comilla, burning alive seven people and injuring around 26
passengers. This time, a case was filed against the leader of the opposition,
Khaleda Zia. In court, her lawyer alleged that the arsonists had been ruling
party leaders out to ruin the image of his client. Of course, neither of the
two Begums (ladies) had been anywhere near the scene of the crime (they never
are, having devoted followers to do their noisome deeds), so it's her word
against the other. Both of them are perfectly capable of ordering such attacks.
As noted, they have evil dispositions.
One could
expand this enumeration of murder; but verb sap. The sensitive will need no
further enlightenment, and for the others (who are many), no amount will
suffice. Let us press on with other, related concerns.
Having looked
at the human toll of hartal, we turn to look at the economic cost, the only
cost that has been stated and analysed by experts (perhaps a Bangladeshi life
has little value). According to the World Bank, during every hartal 5% of GDP
is lost - which works out at $50 billion (The Daily Star, May 3, 2001). In the 1980s, under military dictatorship, Bangladesh used to experience
21 full working days of hartals – in the democratic ‘90s, the figure rose to
47. That is to say, in the '80s there were 21 - failed - attempts to overthrow
General Hossain Mohammed Ershad, and in the '90s there were 47 attempts to
overthrow the democratically elected governments of Khaleda Zia and Sheikh
Hasina, which succeeded. In terms of lost output, the hartals in the first
decade cost $11.05 billion dollars; in the second decade, they cost $23.5
billion: a dirt-poor Bangladesh took economic steps backwards. And the hartals
grew more violent under democracy; under military rule there were no murders,
arson or immolation - the state had not broken down into two warring factions,
the General was firmly in charge. The country subsequently took giant leaps
backwards in its humanity.
This is not paradoxical. As noted above, according to Jason Brennan,
democracy makes us situational enemies. The last chapter of his book Against
Democracy has the title 'Civic Enemies' (pp 231 - 245). “Politics
tends to make us hate each other, even when it shouldn’t. We tend to divide the
world into good and bad guys. We tend to view political debate not as
reasonable disputes about how best to achieve our shared aims but rather as a
battle between the forces of light and darkness. (pp 231-232).”
(Charles Taylor, in his book, A Secular Age, makes a similar
observation: “A Buddhist acquaintance of mine from Thailand briefly visited the
German Greens. He confessed to utter bewilderment. He thought he understood the
goals of the party; peace between human beings, and a stance of respect and
friendship by humans towards nature. But what astonished him was all the anger,
the tone of the denunciation, of hatred towards the established parties. These
people didn’t seem to see that the first step towards their goal would have to
involve stifling the anger and aggression in themselves. He couldn’t understand
what they were up to (Cambridge, Mass: Harvard University Press, 2007, p 698)”.
One is reminded of W. B. Yeats’s lines:
‘…to be
choked with hate
May well be of
all evil chances chief.
If there’s no
hatred in a mind
Assault and
battery of the wind
Can never tear
the linnet from the leaf.’)
This is not
merely an opinion. Massive amounts of research by political scientists, social
psychologists and political psychologists (to be described below) confirm the
observation. The only reason Republicans and Democrats do not burn each other
alive is that the state – and the idea of the state – is strong whereas in
Bangladesh, and indeed the whole of South Asia, the idea of the state is
absent. Loyalty has always been directed towards language, religion and caste.
Thomas Hobbes has never made his presence felt here. Given the fragility of the
state, elections wreak havoc. “The contradiction between a personalised Indian
society and, in theory if not always in practice, an impersonalised colonial
state apparatus became more acute after the introduction of the elective
principle,” observes Ayesha Jalal (Democracy and Authoritarianism in South
Asia, A Comparative and Historical Perspective, Cambridge: Cambridge University
Press, 1995, p 11). In addition, as we will see below, the stakes are low in
the United States.
Having said
that, it must be noted that the term ‘democracy’ has historically had a pejorative
connotation, as we shall see, starting with the father of western political
philosophy himself, Plato (see, for instance, the Republic 496 c-e, and below).
Polybius, probably the last thinker to pronounce on the subject in antiquity,
rechristened democracy into the unholy ‘ochlocracy’ (John Dunn, Setting The
People Free: The Story of Democracy, London: Atlantic Books, 2005, p 57), which
connotation stuck to it like a barnacle well into the eighteenth century, and
which accurately describes its practice today in Bangladesh. “As it entered the
eighteenth century, democracy was still very much a pariah word (p 71).”
No we return
to our subject, the perennial and iniquitous hartals of Bangladesh, the
particular form of pathology that democracy here has taken. On the website Hartals Drain
Bangladesh’s Potential, Christian Prokopp writes: “The shutdown of
significant parts of economic activities and public life, and subsequent severe
negative economic consequences are a deliberate part of hartals.”
Notice the identification of the state with the party: the opposition,
by hurting the state (people, property, the economy), hurts the ruling party
with its hartals. The state exists nowhere beyond the party.
Prokopp bemoans the lack of data on hartals – not an accident, for
accurate data on the economy would show up in newspapers every week how the
political parties were reducing the country’s growth rate. “One of the best
sources is a study by the UNDP ‘Beyond Hartals’ from 2005, which investigates
the hartals of the 1990s.” The hartals of the 1990s, as we saw, for the first
time in our history brought the country to its knees, a post-democratic state
of affairs, and therefore a subject of economic scrutiny. “A core finding of
the UNDP study is that the hartals of the 1990’s in Bangladesh may have reduced
the annual GDP growth by 3-4%. These figures are merely inferred from the
number of hartal days to working days and the total annual GDP. The authors
calculated a 4.5% GDP loss per year on average over the decade.”
However, hartals don’t only have immediate economic
consequences – they impact the future. “Political
instability exacerbated or instigated by hartals furthermore impedes
infrastructure development in electrification and transportation, for example.
Stability and infrastructure are undoubtedly substantial factors for the
economical growth of Bangladesh. Lastly, the local private sector is
discouraged to invest (sic) in such an uncertain environment. Garments
production for example is sensitive to unrest, which obstructs reliable
production and timely export of goods, which is essential to sophisticated,
modern supply chains of foreign buyers.”
More
significantly, hartals condition future assessments of the economy by potential
investors, both local and foreign. The
not only create present death and loss, but generate a stream of ongoing
misery.
Hartal
figures vary for political reasons: no newspaper, as observed, will dare to
report an ongoing tally of economic losses and face the wrath of the parties’
thugs (this theme of self-censorship by the local media will return, but rarely
on account of thugs, though). Thus, we saw above that the Daily Star states
that there were 21 hartals in the pre-democratic ‘80s, and 47 in the democratic
‘90s (the former being very benign compared to those in the ‘90s and
thereafter, as we have observed). The trend, however, seems pretty clear,
despite variations and vagueness in the numbers: hartals have skyrocketed since
our democratic transition. On the Wikipedia page on hartals in Bangladesh, we find 59 days of hartal in the ‘80s,
followed by 266 days in 1991-96, and 215 days in 1996-2001 – that is, a total
of 481 days of hartal in a decade. The Banglapedia
figures, though different, show the same trend, with the worst figures for 2000
– 2002 at 332 days of hartal, followed by 130 in 2003 – 2006 (Banglapedia gives
hartal figures at national, regional and local levels, but only the first have
been considered here, since they are the most virulent). Of the 721 hartals
recorded by the Banglapedia since the country came into being as East Pakistan
in 1947, 591 occurred after the democratic transition of 1990 – that is, 82% in
a mere 21 years (1990 – 2011). The article needs updating since, as we have
seen, there have been many and severe hartals as recently as 2015, when,
according to David Bergman, 61 people died, most of them burnt alive, in
January alone (Bergman notes that altogether 119 people died through political
violence, including hartals, in January and February, 2015).
There
were no hartals at all in 2007 – 2008, a period of peace and good government
fondly recalled even today, when the military, the de facto sovereign, took
over (according to the German legal philosopher, Carl Schmitt, the sovereign is the institution that
succours a nation in extreme circumstances, and the Bangladesh Army has done so
on repeated occasions).
Hartal,
then, appears to be the acme of evil in Bangladesh, the favoured instrument of
Lucifer’s hatred of humankind dwelling in peace before he turned his sulphurous
gaze on this blessed land. Yet, according to the Supreme Court, hartal is a
constitutional right. Yes, anyone with a beef against the government can
legitimately wound, kill, burn, bludgeon, bomb his or her compatriots to
further the cause. “Hartal, though a right, is apt to curtail the rights of
people not willing to participate in it. In that sense, hartal is viewed by
many as a coercive political right,” concludes the Banglapedia article. Only in
a so-called democracy with two dynasties rotating in power using power, naked
and unrestrained, can the oxymoron ‘coercive political right’ be printed
without shame.
Finally,
a word on the international press. Bangladesh receives scant coverage in world
media (it’s an easy-to-miss country, nestled imperceptibly next to India), and
when it does, the result is often distortion. We have seen the centrality of
hartal in the ‘democratic process’ (for want of a better expression). But the
word is untranslatable into English, the world language. This is not an
accident; the meaning of a word arises from the rules for its use in society, the
upshot of the Sapir-Whorf hypothesis and Ludwig Wittgenstein’s stress on the
connection between linguistic activity and a ‘way of life’ (‘translation’, A Dictionary Of Philosophy, ed. Antony Flew (London: Pan Books,
1979). Consequently, you cannot translate between languages: you can’t transfer
a way of life. Therefore, we come across the following in The Economist: “On October 26th [2013] the
two women who for over two decades have dominated politics in the
Muslim-majority country of over 150m spoke on the telephone. It was their first
conversation in many years. Their country was in crisis, on the brink of a
60-hour hartal, or national strike, called by one of them, Khaleda Zia,
leader of the opposition Bangladesh Nationalist Party (BNP).”
Hartal
= national strike.
I’ve
never heard of a national strike; inevitably, the word is a neologism. Now,
there is general strike, defined by Collins online as “a strike by all or most of the
workers of a country, province, city, etc, esp (caps.) such a strike that took
place in Britain in 1926.” The reader of The Economist thus has a nebulous idea
of most Bangladeshi workers downing tools at the behest of the opposition
leader.
“The
hartal went ahead. At least 13 people were killed and 1,000 injured as
thuggish BNP loyalists battled the police for control of the streets, and
hundreds of crude bombs exploded.” Now, the reader must be scratching her head.
How can people get killed or injured in a national/general strike? Why bombs?
Why thugs? It would take several pages of print to convey to the reader the
meaning of the term, as we have had to do above. An anthropological inquiry is
not a newspaper’s remit. The word erects a barrier between two diametrically
opposed civilisations, incommensurable.
Then
there is misinformation. “Nearly 50 people have been killed and more than
10,000 opposition activists arrested,” reported The Economist on February 2, 2015. But we are not told
how they were killed. They were, as
we have seen, burnt alive.
Mistranslation
and misinformation conspire to perpetuate the bad barrel of hartal.
ROTTING THE APPLES
Would
you like to have your own private army – without spending a cent? Impossible?
Not at all. It happens all the time.
The
cheapening of the soldiery is one of the blessings of modernity. Among other
innovations, the post-1789 period in Europe created the citizen army. The
number of soldiers exploded: in 1740, the peacetime Prussian army numbered
80,000 men, that of France, 160,000. In 1914, the peacetime strength of the
German army was 750,000 which swelled to 1,700,000 on a war footing. Excess
reserves and the Landswehr brought
the total that could be brought into the field to 5,300,000; the peacetime
strength of the French army was 800,000, its wartime strength 1,600,000, which,
with reserves, totalled 4,400,000 men And these men were all nationals, unlike
previous soldiers, many of whom had been foreigners (S.E.Finer, The
History of Government from the Earliest Times, (New York: Oxford University
Press, 1997), p 1549).
How did this
remarkable change come about?
Finer continues:
“In the old days, no state could have supported the cost of paying so many
troops. But now they did not have to pay them more than a mere pittance. Here
was a complete contrast to the eighteenth century: after all, it was the cost
of the American War that led to the financial crisis in France and thereby the
Revolution. This was all turned on its head, and the reason for it was that by
now the ideology of nationalism had
gripped the masses. It no longer seemed exceptional to be a soldier. Every
able-bodied man regarded this, now, as a sacred duty. That is how, when 1914
came, so many millions of men went to their graves like sheep” (pp 1552-1553)
(italics original).
We are no longer
dealing with Homo economicus, who
carefully weighs costs and benefits, but with Homo psychologicus, the irrational agent (I owe this neat little
distinction to David Houghton).
In Bangladesh,
the student politicians serve as private armies to the two royal families, the
House of Mujib and the House of Zia (currently incarnated in Sheikh Hasina,
Mujib’s daughter, and Khaleda Zia, Zia’s widow, the leaders of the two
political parties).
The ruling Awami
League’s student front is called the Chatra League (Chatra means student), and
it also has a youth wing called the Jubo League (Jubo means young); the
corresponding bodies of the opposition Bangladesh Nationalist Party are the
Jatiyatabadi (nationalist) Chatra Dal (JCD) and Jatiyatabadi Jubo Dal.
Collectively, they may be compared to the Hitler Youth or Mao Zedong’s Red
Guards.
The respectable
appellation ‘student politician’ would, however, be inapt. As we have seen,
they are monsters. I suggest the term ‘student thugs’, to capture the genus and
species: ‘student’ because they are not hired musclemen, and ‘thug’ because
most students are their antithesis, diligent and pacific.
They are the
personnel behind the hartals. Without
them, there would be no bombings, no immolations. That is to say, they are
indispensable to the parties and their leaders.
Their
extra-rational loyalty to their respective leaders stems from the same madness
as inspired the European armies: nationalism. (Notice that the people never
participate in hartals: nationalism, unlike in Europe, never reached the masses
here. It is an elite phenomenon, and thereby a contradiction. That should not
be a surprise: the meaning of a word, as we have seen, cannot be transferred to
another way of life. But that’s not the only contradiction: Mujib and his
daughter’s nationalism is Bengali nationalism – Bengalism – and is anti-Islam,
pro-India and strongly flavoured by Hinduism; Zia and his widow’s nationalism
is Bangladeshi nationalism, pro-Islam, anti-Indian, pro-Pakistan. Thus, two
rival nationalisms coexist, though the former is usually classed as more
nationalist. But both claim extraterritorial loyalty to foreign countries, yet
another contradiction. However, an ersatz nationalism is just as heady – and
toxic – as the real McCoy.)
These are not
revelations: everyone knows about the use of student thugs in politics. Quondam
president and chief justice Shahabuddin Ahmed observed that “students are
getting guns instead of education.” “He reiterated his stand against the
‘political use of students and urged the students to sever connections with the
political parties’ (The
Daily Star, July 11, 2000)” He became enormously popular for his ineffective
jeremiads. Another former president, A. Q. M.
Badruddoza Chowdhury, thundered, “Students are armed to punish the
opposition and we strongly condemn such acts” (The Bangladesh Observer, March 30, 2005).
When the Colombian
FARC pressed children into military service,
right-thinking people were appalled. When our political parties press children
into thuggery, everybody turns a blind eye.
Donor-financed NGOs, which routinely publish the number of murders and
rapes every year, never mention these young rogues, and their fate (their
rational motives for ignoring the demise of student thugs have been detailed in
The
Freedom Industry).
These young boys
(always boys) are filled with what the Greeks called ‘thumos’ – spiritedness.
They are a lot like animals – lightly instructed, highly motivated, savagely
instinctive.
“Do you think,
said I, that there is any difference between the nature of a well-bred hound
for this watchdog’s work and that of a well-born lad (Plato, The Republic 374e
– 375a, trans. Paul Shorey, Plato: The Collected Dialogues, ed. Edith Hamilton
and Huntington Cairns, Princeton: Princeton University Press, 1996)?”
Further: “And
will a creature be ready to be brave that is not high-spirited, whether horse
or dog or anything else? Have you never observed what an irresistible and
invincible thing is spirit, the presence of which makes every soul in the face
of everything fearless and unconquerable?
“I have.
“The physical
qualities of the guardian, then, are obvious.
“Yes.
“And also those
of his soul, namely that he must be of high spirit.
“Yes, this too.
“How then,
Glaucon, said I, will they escape from being savage to one another and to the
other citizens if this is to be their nature?
“Not easily, by
Zeus, said I. (Republic 375a – b).”
Not easily,
indeed. Notre Dame College in the capital, Dhaka, is famed for keeping student
politics out of the campus, unlike its opposite, the infamous Dhaka College. In
1991, the year after the annus mirabilis
of our democratic transition brought about by these heroic, freedom-loving
student politicians, as the myth goes, I went over to Notre Dame College, my alma mater, and spoke at length with Fr.
Joseph Peixotto, the principal, and Fr. James Banas, the vice-principal. I
asked them how they managed to keep students out of politics, and their answer
was simple: whenever a student got into politics, they called the parents, and
they would immediately pull him out. Obedience and conformity are built into
the culture, but these can also be used by the political parties, which, in
effect, become surrogate family, the founder serving as a father figure at the
locus of a personality cult.
A recommendation
from the principal of Notre Dame College weighs heavily in favour of students
with the admissions departments of American universities. However much America
may admire our student politicians, they don’t want them running amok on campuses
there. But the padres of Notre Dame, which now holds the campus of Notre Dame
University here, almost failed to stem the rot.
In 1974, the son
of the prime minister, regarded by followers as the pater patriae, stormed into
the campus with his thugs, cutting off electricity and intimidating the
residents. The Fathers informed the police, but they were solidly behind the
scion. The Fathers put on their cassocks, and heard him out. Sheikh Kamal
demanded student politics. The priests agreed, but had secretly decided to
leave the country. Sheikh Kamal sensed this, and never came back.
(It cannot be
over-emphasised that these students are boys, minors, children. College in
Bangladesh is high school. They enter college in their sixteenth year and exit
in their seventeenth. The voting age in Bangladesh is eighteen.)
Consider the
inference that Socrates draws from his observation of dogs.
“And does it seem
to you that our guardian-to-be will also need, in addition to the being
high-spirited [thumos], the further quality of having the love of wisdom in his
nature?
“How so, he said.
I don’t apprehend your meaning.
“This too, said
I, is something that you will discover in dogs and and which is worth our
wonder in the creature.
“What?
“That the sight
of an unknown person angers him before he has suffered any injury, but an
acquaintance he will fawn upon though he has never received any kindness from
him. Have you never marveled at that?
“I never paid any
attention to the matter before now, but that he acts in some such way is
obvious.
“But surely that
is an exquisite trait of his nature and one that shows a true love of wisdom.
“In what respect,
pray?
“In respect, said
I, that he distinguishes a friendly from a hostile aspect by nothing save his
apprehension of the one and his failure to recognize the other. How, I ask you,
can the love of learning be denied to a creature whose criterion of the friendly
and the alien is intelligence and ignorance?”
Socrates
concludes: “Then may we not confidently lay it down, in the case of man too,
that if he is to be in some sort gentle to friends and familiars he must be by
nature a lover of wisdom and learning (Republic 376a – c)?”
Love of wisdom
and learning, philosophia, are, of
course, the last thing on the minds of student thugs. The believe they know
everything; certainly enough to decide who should rule the state.
The domestication
of the spiritedness of Glaucon constitutes the master-question of the Republic.
But might not the spirited part of the soul degenerate into the appetitive
part, represented in the dialogue by Adimantus? Might not Glaucon become
acquisitive? But that is not the worst fate than can befall the spirited. The
worst fate is the criminalization of the thumotic soul.
It was in the
year 1991, the year following our annus
horribilis, that I made my first contact with a student thug. His name was
Nanno (I never cared to learn his last name). He was a leader of the Chatra
League, the student front of the Awami League, then in opposition. His elder
brother, Liaquat, was in jail, and Nanno had logically inherited leadership of
the local mafiosi. of Eskaton, where my parents lived.
He rang the bell,
and our servant opened the gate, and received a slap. Nanno swaggered into the
driveway, sidekick in train, and was met by my father at the door. My mother
stood behind him, rooted. They noticed the butt of a gun protruding from his
pocket.
“They’re going to
kill you,” he said.
My father had
been chairman of the Bangladesh Textile Mills Corporation and had brought
militant trade union leaders to heel. He knew how to negotiate.
“Then let them
kill me.”
“No, no, why
should they kill you?”
Abba had just
sold the property, and Nanno knew of the transaction, and demanded his share,
Takas 200,000 ($5,000 at the time).
He left, and the
talks went on for a few days. Fortunately, my wife and I were not living with
my parents at the time; otherwise, he might have slapped us around to impress
them.
It didn’t even occur
to us to go to the police. My parents had connections in the Awami League, but
they were told they had to pay up; the money would go to the top.
When I learned
what had happened, I made a phone call, and summoned eight professional
murderers in my living room, most of them bleary-eyed with booze. They came
pillion-riding noisily on four motorcycles, and made quite an impression on the
guards.
“Tell us what we
have to do,” barked the boss.
My father smiled
and shook his head. I was young, and he was old. I had only one concern, their
safety, and I didn’t care what I had to do to get it. There was no state to
protect us.
I don’t know how
much he paid Nanno, but they soon moved out and into an apartment building
secured 24 hours by guards.
Homo psychologicus has graduated to Homo
economicus. But sometimes, the thumotic soul just loses its thumos, as
happened with Javed (not his real name).
It was in the
year 1991 again, the year after the miraculous or terrible year, according to
taste and judgment, that I sought out a quondam student thug and interviewed
him in-depth. Javed was now in retirement, drug-addled and living off his
family, a drop-out. He had been one of the heroes who supposedly toppled
General Ershad. A psychiatrist I spoke to, Dr. Mirza M. Huq, confirmed that “it
is not uncommon for students involved in politics to be addicted to drugs”. He
was on the hit-list of the opposition, so moved to another city. His relatives
shunned him. One observed, “He can kill a man in cold blood, and no one could
tell by looking at his face”. Family pariah, national (and international) hero:
such was the fate of student politicians. (A transcript and translation of the
interview can be read here.)
Javed joined the
party when he was fourteen (in 1988). By the age of fifteen, he was an armed
member.
““How I got hold of arms. The aim was to
organise a program at school, save money and buy arms. The teachers tried to
stop us, but we went ahead with the program. We also collected tolls [extortion
money] from businessmen in the area. Then we bought arms from an iron-smith.
Pipe-gun, 250 takas ($6); cocktail, 1100 takas.
“After
this episode, the party started giving us total assistance. They started to
send boys from the armed cadres, or cells. They were our age; they didn’t
attend school. Their sources of income were gambling, black marketing in cinema
tickets, mugging, selling drugs, and extorting money from hawkers and
shop-owners. These were ‘taxes’. Taxes were collected on a fairly regular
weekly basis. The cadre boys would receive tax proportionate to the area they
could control”.
Javed
didn’t tell me if he had murdered anyone, and I didn’t ask. Some things can’t
be talked about. But his peers did. After several rehabs, several lost jobs, a
failed marriage, today he has a job, a wife and a son. He lives with his
parents. But who will give him back the best years of his life? (Paradoxically,
he’s still fiercely loyal to the party that exploited his youth; as a rule, the
more severe the initiation, the greater the loyalty to the group (The Lucifer
Effect, p 376)).
He
is lucky to be alive. Between 2001 and 2018, the number of student thugs
murdered stood at 872 (including members of youth fronts), an average of 48 per
year, or 4 per month. This is a typical news item: “Munshiganj, May 23 – Joint
Secretary of Munshiganj City Chatra League [opposition party student wing]
Masum Mia (28) was beaten to death....According to a report, the deceased
Chatra league leader came under the attack of the assailants when he was found
on the road. The attackers started beating him with sticks and fled the scene
leaving the victim. When the body was taken to the Sadar hospital, the doctors
declared him dead. The Sadar Thana police said there were some cases against
the deceased Chatra League leader (The Bangladesh Observer, May 26, 2003)”. A
chart showing the number of newspaper headlines announcing the murder of
student politicians can be found here (note the steep decline in the number of murders under
military rule in 2007-8, and subsequent surge).
These
young men are not killed by the authorities. They kill each other, almost
always in the same political group, after they fall out among themselves over a
division of the spoils. Homo economicus
has gone into business. They typically collect extortion money from businesses
in their designated areas. Nanno and his brother Liaquat, as we have seen,
controlled the area of Eskaton in the capital, where my parents lived.
Newspapers
and NGOs in Bangladesh have never carried out a study of the extent of Danegeld
in the country (as opposed to say, delving deep into the number of young people
watching pornography). This is understandable and,
unfortunately, rational. The statistics would reflect badly on our donor-enforced
democracy. Anecdotal evidence suggests extortion levels must be high: In El Salvador, extortion amounts to 16% of GDP.
However,
in 2007, only 10 youths were killed and the next year the figure fell to 8. In
2007-8, the military took over the country, under General Moeen U Ahmed. These
were memorable years of peace and stability. The highest number of murders
occurred in the year 2013, when the tally reached 110.
Between
1985 and 2000, 15 students were murdered at Tejgaon Polytechnik Institute (The
Daily Star, 3rd April, 2000). They all belonged to political
parties. The age of graduation from the institute is 18, so they must have been
around 17 years of age. The 5 students killed in 1985 belonged to the Jatiya
Chatra Samaj, the student front of the Jatiya Party, the party of then ruler,
General H M Ershad. Ershad disbanded the Jatiya Chatra Samaj, realising his
boys couldn’t cope with the other groups.
Why
did Ershad fail to create loyal student thugs? Why couldn’t he channel their
thumos?
He
was the anti-hero. He had no ideology, no convictions or beliefs. He was
personally corrupt. He rigged elections. He made Machiavellian use of religion:
when it didn’t rain, he gathered his followers and prayed in the open. And then
it rained. (In addition, he was a womanizer, while still married. He flaunted
his mistresses, who were some of the most beautiful women in Bangladesh.) Loyalty
to Ershad was based on rational considerations: money. He dispensed patronage.
But he couldn’t buy the thumos of the students. They were Homo psychologicus,
not Homo economicus, not the acquisitive soul.
This
‘rotting of the apples’ is not confined to student thugs. The ‘bad barrel of
democracy’ has affected the entire society, even the person-in-the-street. Lynching,
for instance, was virtually unknown pre-democracy, under Generals Ershad and
Zia. A thief caught by a mob would be beaten up and handed over to the police.
This testified to the low levels of crime and violence under these rulers, and
to a certain degree of faith in the justice system. When political parties
themselves became criminalised, and violence soared, this faith fell apart.
Mobs began to beat alleged thieves, muggers and robbers to death – and worse.
“[The] Catching
[of] an alleged mugger and setting him on fire by pouring kerosene all over his
body at Mirpur last Monday night raked up a nightmarish memory. We can't forget
that not so long ago lynching became a regular occurrence just about anywhere
(sic) in the country. But mostly alleged muggers would either be burnt to death
or set on fire by angry crowds in broad daylight in the capital city.....(The
Daily Star, January 12, 2003).” Between 2006 and 2018, newspapers have reported
677 incidents of lynching; that is, 52 per year and around 4 every month, with
the highest total recorded so far in 2011, 98.
Lynching, no
doubt, is a rational response to a failing and criminalized state, but the violence
meted out seems sometimes disproportionate.
Given the
lawlessness in the country, with the two major political parties in the van of
all things, the parties sought to assuage the public and hamstring the
opposition with a series of ‘repressive’ laws. Laws curtailing fundamental
rights had never been passed under military rule; there had been no scope or
need. The ‘Special Powers Act’ had been passed in 1972 by the democratically
elected Awami League under similar circumstances; Prevention of Terrorism Act
was passed by the BNP in 1992-94; Public Safety Act (Awami League, 2000 –
2002); Offences Disrupting Law and Order (Summary Trial) (BNP, 2002); Speedy
Trial Tribunal Act (BNP, 2002); Digital Security Act (Awami League, 2018).
Extra-judicial
killing appeared for the first time since 1975. In the last ten months of 2018,
there have been 437 extrajudicial killings, according to reports. They
began with ‘Operation
Clean Heart’ under prime minister Khaleda Zia of the BNP: between
16th October 2003 and 9th January 2004, the military
arrested 11,245 suspects, more than 40 of whom died in custody.
Then there are
the disappearances. Meenakshi Ganguly, the South Asia director at Human Rights
Watch, said the "spate of secret detentions and enforced
disappearances" have become commonplace in Bangladesh in recent years,
according to Al
Jazeera.
"While some
people were released after weeks, even months, in illegal custody, others were
later discovered to have been killed in so-called 'armed exchanges'," she
said.
Dhaka-based human
rights group Odhikar estimates up to 414 individuals have gone missing between
2009 (when the Awami League government came to power after the military
interregnum) and 2017. In 2017, Odhikar reported a further 86 disappearances. A
report by Human Rights Watch published last year found that at least 90 people
were victims of enforced disappearances in 2016 alone, 21 of whom were
subsequently found dead.
Bangladesh's
elite Rapid Action Battalion (RAB), a special paramilitary unit, is alleged to
be behind most of the disappearances. A Human Rights Watch in its report
published in 2011 said the RAB has a "long record of killing people in
custody". The Rapid Action Battalion was created by Khaleda Zia when she
was prime minister; it proved so popular that her rival Sheikh Hasina kept it
on into her own tenure.
State
violence and street violence complement each other.
THE IRRATIONAL
We
have seen that lynching, extortion, even extrajudicial killing (which makes the
government appear to be in charge), disappearances (largely directed at the
opposition) are rational responses to an irrational situation – loyalty to two toxic
leaders, or dynasties, in competition for power, instead of loyalty towards the
state.
As
early as 1908 - while Sigmund Freud was studying his patients in Vienna - Graham Wallas, a professor at the London
School of Economics and Political Science (LSE), in his book Human Nature in
Politics, warned against viewing every human action and decision as the result
of a rational, intellectual process (Political Psychology, p 24). This was in
the tradition of Hippolyte Taine and Gustave Le Bon in the 1800s in France.
Muzafer
Sherif, a Turkish social psychologist, emigrated to America. He reasoned, strangely
enough, that, America being a democracy, Americans would tend to be conformists
because their democracy emphasised mutually shared agreements (The Lucifer
Effect, p 262). In the early 1950s, he devised an ingenious experiment at
Robber’s Cave, Oklahoma, to test his hunch. He took twenty-two schoolboys, none
of whom knew each other, to a summer camp and divided them randomly into two
groups. He had screened the boys for pathological traits to rule out any
dispositional effects. Each group was then separated from the other for a week,
during which time they developed their own leaders, identity and culture. Sherif
then threw the two groups into a series of competitive activities and games.
“Hostility quickly emerged between the two groups, to the point where they
could not engage in non-competitive activities without insulting and even
fighting one another (Political Psychology, p 170).” Mere, arbitrary
classification of the boys into two groups sufficed to create hostility, a
situational effect. Political parties,
divided by personality, ideology, history and values must generate far greater
hatred. In Sherif’s experiment, nothing
was at stake; in national politics, issues like language, religion, money
create a life-and-death struggle, as we have seen. Democracy makes us
situational enemies, to repeat Jason Brennan’s felicitous expression. Yet democratic
disputes in America are far removed from democratic disputes here.
“It’s
especially bizarre,” observes Brennan, “that mainstream political discussion is
so heated and apocalyptic, given how
little is at stake. Republicans and Democrats disagree about many things,
but in the logical space of possible political views they’re not merely in the
same solar system but also on the same planet. They’re not debating deep
existential questions about justice but instead surface disputes about the
exact shape of the society they mutually accept. They’ve both agreed to buy the
Camry; they’re now just debating whether to accept the sports package or hybrid
(Against Democracy, p 232) (italics original). In Bangladesh, parties contend
over whether to get the Uzi or the Kalashnikov – to use against the other side.
In
1955, however, Sherif’s findings were challenged by social psychologist,
Solomon Asch. Asch believed that Americans could act autonomously even when the
group challenged his/view. To test this, he devised an experiment in which he
showed subjects four perpendicular lines, A, B, C and X, where C and X were the
same length, and the others shorter or longer. Asch speculated that even if the
group gave the wrong answer – A = X, or B = X – the individual would not
subscribe to a transparent falsehood.
The
subject made few mistakes (less than 1 percent of the time). But there were
seven other members of the group (who were Asch’s confederates posing as
subjects). They were instructed to give incorrect answers unanimously on
specific ‘critical’ trials.
Of
the 123 participants in Asch’s study, the individual yielded to the group 70
percent of the time on some of those critical trials. Thirty percent of the
subjects conformed on the majority of trials, and only a quarter of them
maintained their independence throughout the testing.
We
conform out of two needs: informational needs (other people will have knowledge
that may be useful), and normative needs (other people will accept us more if
we agree with them, the need to belong.
Technology,
unavailable in Asch’s time, now allows us to peer into the mind – literally. Functional
magnetic resonance imaging (FMRI) scans reveal which parts of the brain are
active – ‘light up’ – during the experiment. When we yield to the group’s
erroneous judgment. Conformity shows up in the brain scan as changes in
selected regions of the brain’s cortex dedicated to vision and spatial
awareness (specifically, activity increases in the right intraparietal
sulcus). However, if you make independent judgements
that go against the group, our brain would light up in the areas associated
with emotional salience (the right amygdala and the right caudate nuclear
regions). This shows that resistance to the group creates an emotional burden
for those who maintain their independence. That is to say, autonomy comes at a psychic cost. (For a literary rendition of the
psychic cost of independence, the reader is directed to the masterly short
story by D H Lawrence, England, My England.)
“We
like to think that seeing is believing,” observes neuroscientist Gregory Berns,
“but the study’s finding shows that seeing is believing what the group tells
you to believe. (The Lucifer Effect, pp 263 – 265).”
Jason
Brennan divides the citizenry into three groups: hobbits, hooligans, and
vulcans. Hobbits are apathetic non-voters. They have little or no knowledge of
current affairs, economics or politics – and no interest in these matters.
Hooligans are passionate about politics, well-informed but biased. They
cherry-pick information to suit their party-political views. “For them,
belonging to the Democrats or Republicans, Labour or Tories, or Social
Democrats or Christian Democrats matters to their self-image in the same way
being a Christian or Muslim matters to religious people’s self-image.” Vulcans
are the rarae avis, unbiased and rational;
they proportion their belief to the evidence. Their views are grounded in the
social sciences and philosophy. Most people are either hobbits or hooligans
(Against Democracy, pp 4 – 5).
However,
hooligans don’t kill each other, so we need a fourth category for Bangladesh:
student thugs. Hooligans in Bangladesh provide moral support to the student
thugs. Obedience to authority perceived as legitimate – authority which is
legitimised by hooligans and the democratic process – galvanise students to
commit the vilest of acts. We have seen how, in the experiment by Muzafer
Sherif, ingroup-outgroup hostility can occur even in the absence of any
material stake. And group pressure overrides the individual’s autonomy. All of
us are capable of extreme evil in an obedient herd.
During
the 1960s, Stanley Milgram conducted a series of experiments destined to be
famous – or infamous – in New Haven, Connecticut. These were investigations of
‘blind obedience to authority”. Milgram’s motivation was to understand how
readily the Nazis had obediently killed Jews during the Holocaust (being a Jew
himself, he had an acute interest in the subject).
Milgram
put an advertisement in the newspaper offering $4 (plus 50 cents care fare) for
approximately one hour to help ‘complete a scientific study of memory and
learning’. Participants were told that they were to help scientific psychology
to improve people’s learning and memory through the use of punishment (electric
shocks). The shocks were graduated at thirty levels, each switch increasing the
shock by 15 volts, so the maximum was 450 volts (labelled XXX). The
participant, the ‘teacher’, had to administer the shocks to a ‘learner’ every
time he got an answer wrong, going up one switch each time. The ‘learner’ was a
confederate, and the shocks were simulated, but the ‘teachers’ didn’t know
that. The learner would complain verbally and scream out his words of agony at
high levels of shock.
Prior
to the experiment, Milgram asked forty psychiatrists what percentage of
Americans would go to each of the thirty levels of the experiment. On average,
they predicted that less than 1% would go all the way to the end, that only
sadists would engage in such behaviour, and that most people would drop out at
the level of 150 volts.
In
the event, 2 out of 3 (65%) volunteers went all the way up to the maximum shock
level of 450 volts – even though they could hear nothing from the
learner-victim assumed to be unconscious or dead (The Lucifer Effect, pp 267 –
271).
David
Mantell, who repeated Milgram’s study in Munich, Germany found an obedience
rate of 85% - 20 percentage points higher than in New Haven. David Houghton tentatively
attempts to understand the Rwandan genocide of 1994 in terms of obedience to
authority. He quotes a lawyer from Kigali, with a Hutu father and a Tutsi
mother: “Conformity is very deep, very developed. In Rwandan history, everyone
obeys authority. People revere power, and there isn’t enough education.
(Political Psychology, p 52).”
In
a vertical, hierarchic society such as ours in Bangladesh, this observation
would be equally true.
Obedience
to authority, however, is innate, according to Stanley Milgram. We are born
with a disposition to obey, as part of our evolutionary psychology; but there’s
more to it than that. Our disposition to obey interacts with social structures
and specific circumstances – in short, situations – to produce special cases of
obedience (Political Psychology, p 52). Hannah Arendt famously coined the
expression “the banality of evil”. We’ve noted how Javed and his peers,
school-going teenagers, became student thugs. But obedience is obedience to
authority, and therefore leadership plays a central role in directing evil.
According to
David Reynolds:” But as we shall also see in Yugoslavia, ethnicity is rarely a
spontaneous force. It needs to be manipulated by politicians. What mattered in
Rwanda was the reaction of Hutu hard-liners in the party and the army to their
impending loss of power” (One World Divisible: A Global History Since
1945 (New York: W.W.Norton and Co.,
2000), pp. 606-607).
The
Rwandan genocide was meticulously planned by Hutu army
officers and politicians to avoid sharing power with Tutsi rebels after a peace
accord to end a civil war. They raised a militia, cranked up the genocidal
propaganda and imported hundreds of thousands of machetes in advance. The
outside world barely noticed until it was too late. The genocide ended only when
a Tutsi army swept in to stop it, led by Rwanda’s current president, Paul
Kagame.
The
lawyer from Kigali continues: “You take a poor, ignorant population, and give
them arms, and say, ‘It’s yours. Kill.’ They’ll obey. The peasants, who were
paid or forced to kill, were looking up to people of higher socio-economic
standing to see how to behave. So the people of influence […] are often the big
men in the genocide. They may think that they didn’t kill because they didn’t
take life with their own hands, but the people were looking to them for their
orders. And, in Rwanda, an order can be given very quietly.”
The
allure of toxic leaders can never be explained rationally. The leadership
itself may behave rationally, but their cultish followers are hard to fathom. The
extra-rational loyalty of student thugs in Bangladesh to their respective
leaders is a case in point.
What
depths can obedience plumb? That question was answered on November 28, 1978 in
the jungles of Guyana. It is one thing to kill your neighbour, but a different
thing to kill your own children on command. The command was given by Jim Jones
to his 900-plus followers to drink Kool-Aid laced with cyanide. Most of them obeyed willingly. Jim Jones had
been a pastor of Peoples Temple in San Francisco and Los Angeles. He set out to
create a socialist utopia in the South American country, where brotherhood and
tolerance were to replace the materialism and racism of the United States. He
became an egomaniacal tyrant and ultimately an Angel of Death (The Lucifer
Effect, pp 294 – 295). One is reminded of the worship of Moloch. And if people
can follow Jim Jones, they can follow anyone.
Note,
however, that 35% of Milgram’s participants did not go along with the
researcher. They appear to have had what may be termed ‘good’ dispositions. But
dispositions do not guarantee immunity from evil. Philip Zimbardo questions the
‘good-evil’ dichotomy, arguing instead that the distinction is permeable and
nebulous. Given the right – or wrong – situation, we are all capable of
committing acts of evil.
In
1971, Zimbardo, then a young professor of psychology at Stanford University,
was interested in studying the effects of prison roles on behaviour. Like
Milgram, he put an advertisement in the newspaper, and selected twenty-two
participants, after carefully screening them for any kind of abnormality. The
‘prison’ was located in the basement of the Stanford Psychology Department. To
make the situation seem more real, he had the Palo Alto police ‘charge’ the ‘prisoners’
in public mock arrests. When they arrived at the prison, they were made to
strip, delouse and forced to wear specially designed smocks.
Within
two days, the situation began to take over. Some guards became sadistic and
devised ingenious ways to humiliate and intimidate the prisoners (physical
violence was not allowed). One guard, nicknamed ‘John Wayne’ by the prisoners,
was especially adept at devising new kinds of torment. He played sexual games
in which he ‘forced’ prisoners to perform acts of sodomy. Some prisoners
rebelled, others became passive and some appeared to have emotional breakdowns.
After six days, the experiment had to be stopped, but only after Christina
Maslach, Zimbardo’s graduate assistant and a relative outsider (whom he later
married), expressed her shock at the evil of the situation.
Zimbardo’s
explanation for what had transpired was the ‘bad barrel’ theory (already mentioned).
The system (barrel-makers) create the ‘barrel’ (situation) that produces the
‘bad apples’. Put good young men in a bad situation, and the situation will
quickly override their dispositions. When the Abu Ghraib scandal broke,
Zimbardo was shocked, but not surprised. It was eerily redolent of the Stanford
Prison Experiment (SPE). He tried to help in the defence of Sergeant Ivan
“Chip” Frederick, one of the soldiers who was photographed grinning beside a
pyramid of naked Iraqi prisoners. His aim was not to have Frederick exonerated,
but to have his sentence made lighter. The Western legal system, however, is
strongly dispositionist, and the judge rejected Zimbardo’s situationist
argument.
The
SPE has often been referred to as the ‘Lord of the Flies’ effect, after the
novel of the same name by William Golding. The novel is about a group of boys
marooned on a tropical island (possibly after a nuclear war). Without any
authority, the boys descend into aggressive behaviour, in a Hobbesian ‘war of
all against wall’. David Houghton describes Hobbes as a dispositionist, someone
who views human nature as essentially evil (Political Psychology, pp 60 – 61).
I beg to disagree. Hobbes was very much a situationist, maintaining that,
absent the sovereign, people will be in ‘a state of nature’, perpetually at war
with one another. But, given the sovereign, there will not only be peace, but
flourishing.
“In such condition, there is no place
for Industry; because the fruit thereof is uncertain; and consequently no
Culture of the Earth; no Navigation, nor use of the commodities that may be
imported by Sea; no commodious Building; no Instruments of moving, and removing
such things as require much force; no Knowledge of the face of the Earth; no
account of Time; no Arts; no Letters; no Society; and which is worst of all,
continuall feare, and danger of violent death; And the life of man, solitary, poore,
nasty, brutish, and short (Leviathan, Chapter 13).”
It is not only the fear of death that motivates humans
to seek peace, but also a "Desire of
such things as are necessary to commodious living; and a Hope by their Industry
to obtain them”. That does not sound like a disposition to wickedness.
Hobbes’s ‘state
of nature’ may be regarded as a piece of didactic fiction, or, at best, a
conjecture. Recent research has, however, proved him to be more right than he
himself would have believed.
Archaeological
and anthropological studies have shown that in simple agricultural societies
with no political framework beyond village and tribe, life was, and still is,
‘nasty, brutish and short’. Human
violence contributed to 15% of deaths, including 25% of male deaths. In New
Guinea today, violence kills 30% of males in one agricultural tribal society,
the Dani, and 25% in another, the Enga, In Ecuador, perhaps 50% of adult
Waoranis are killed by other humans. It took larger political frameworks – cities,
kingdoms and states - to bring human violence under control (Yuval Noah Harari,
Sapiens: A Brief History of Humankind, Croydon: Vintage, 2014, p 93).
Besides, in the
Middle East, we have seen that when the state collapses, chaos and bloodshed
reign. Hobbes was not wrong. Consider the
number of homicides in Iraq in the late 2000s after the removal of Saddam Hussein
and the Baathist state: the figure stood at 3,700 per month. With the fall of the government of Libya and
the civil war in Syria, the entire Middle East turned into “bellum omnium
contra omnes”. Even as late as May 2016, Emma
Sky, a former adviser to the military in Iraq, suggested viewing the
conflict as “a struggle for power and resources in a collapsing state. A
Hobbesian war of all against all”.
WHO KILLED MAHIMA?
Mahima didn’t
commit suicide; she was killed. By whom?
We begin our
investigation with the lowest rung: the voters.
Bangladesh was
conceived in hatred. The first nationwide elections were held in 1970, more
than two decades after the creation of Pakistan in 1947. Two demagogues, one
from the east, Sheikh Mujib, and one from the west, Zulfiquar Ali Bhutto, contested
the election. They were both orators of the first caliber, and could rouse the
rabble (Ayesha Jalal, in her book, uses the term ‘populist’ (p 66), but I
prefer the classical, Aristotelian term) - for ‘the orators lead the people’
(Aristotle, Politics, 1305 a1 12).
They appealed to
the poor, with the added twist here that the ‘rich’ were located in West
Pakistan, when, in fact, they were mostly a coterie of Punjabis (p 50) :
Pakistan, like many countries, was an oligarchy.
"Brothers," Mujib
would say to his Bengali followers, "do you know that the streets of
Karachi are lined with gold? Do you want to take back that gold? Then raise
your hands and join me."
The poor majority
in East Pakistan spoke Bengali, so linguistic nationalism was also stirred up. West
Pakistan was a polyglot nation, but, with 1,000 miles separating the two wings
of the country, the voters in the east felt they were a homogeneous lot, ‘the
enemy’ who did not speak our language. A civil war followed, and East Pakistan
broke away to form Bangladesh.
Grievance is not
a fact. It has to be articulated, stimulated and directed by a leader. We have
seen the role that leaders play in fomenting hatred. We have also seen how
‘ingroup-outgroup’ hostility can exist purely on the basis of division, with
the two groups identical in every respect. This is not rational. “Politics
makes us hate each other, even when it shouldn’t” concludes Jason Brennan
(Against Democracy, p 231). He observes that voters are ‘ignorant, irrational,
misinformed nationalists’ (p 23).
“What voters
don’t know would fill a library” notes Bryan Caplan in The Myth of The Rational
Voter: Why Democracies Choose Bad Policies’ (quoted, pp 28 – 29). Ilya Somin,
author of Democracy and Political Ignorance, found, upon empirical research,
that at least 35% of voters are know-nothings. Political scientist Larry
Bartels notes that “the political ignorance of the American voter is one of the
best-documented features of contemporary politics” (p 25). And here we are dealing with the political
situation in America, where more than 80% of white people over twenty-five have
a high school diploma, and information is inexpensively available; yet people
know as little about politics as they did 40 years ago. Americans don’t know
history, economics or about politics and current affairs More than 25% of
Americans don’t know whom they fought against in the Revolutionary War (p 29). In
1964, only a minority of citizens knew that the Soviet Union was not a member of NATO. This was two years
after the Cuban Missile Crisis when America nearly went to - nuclear - war
against the Soviet Union. 40% of Americans do not know whom the United States
fought in World War II. 73% of Americans do not know what the Cold War was
about (p 26).
It is frequently
argued that at least democracy allows voters to ‘kick out the bastards’. But
how does one tell who the bastards are, what they did, what they could have
done, what the opposition intends to do…and so on. This requires a great deal
of social scientific knowledge. Whether I decide on free trade or
protectionism, for instance, requires a knowledge of economics. But, in
Bangladesh, as we will see, voters cannot even kick out the bastards, and have
an unpleasant choice between two equal bastards.
British social
psychologist Henri Tajfel has found that hostility towards outgroups and
favouritism towards one’s own can occur in the absence of any interaction
between them and in the absence of any ‘reasonable’ or ‘rational’ differences
between the groups (Political Psychology, p 171). The ‘situation’, and not the
‘disposition’, makes the difference. In this respect, we are all Homo psychologicus.
Tajfel divided
individuals randomly into two groups based on such frivolous criterion as their
opinion of indistinguishable abstract artists they had never heard of: those
favouring ‘the Paul Klee style’ and those favouring ‘the Kandinsky style’. To
his surprise, the individuals displayed extra-rational loyalty to the ingroup
and hostility to the outgroup. When sharing financial resources, they chose to
penalize the outgroup rather than receive more money themselves.
Political
psychologist Geoffrey Cohen did a number of scientific studies to determine how
political partisanship – or what is sometimes unflatteringly called ‘tribalism’
– affects judgment about policy issues. The experiments presented participants
with two contrasting alternatives – stringent or generous – of a social welfare
policy. Judging each policy on its merits, participants chose the policy
consistent with their ideological views. However, when the policies were
attributed to either the Republican or the Democratic Party, liberals preferred
the Democratic-labeled policy regardless of whether it was generous or stringent,
and conservatives favoured the Republican-labeled policy regardless of the
details (Against Democracy, pp 40 – 41).
People were not
processing information rationally, but being faithful to the team.
A number of
voters describe themselves as independent, but study after study shows that
they are closet partisans. This lends credence to the party identification model developed in the 1960s by Angus Campbell
and his colleagues at the University of Michigan (Political Psychology, pp 157
– 159). Most voters develop a long-term emotional attachment to a particular
political party during their formative or teenage years.
Philip Converse
argued that voters lack ‘attitude constraint’. Mass studies since the 1940s
have shown that voters are political naïfs. They possessed low levels of
information about politics and paid little attention to what was going on in
the political world (redolent of Brennan’s ‘hobbits’). They had no worked-out
ideology; indeed, their political views were ‘all over the place’. They were
liberal on some issues and conservative on others; most of them did not know
what the terms ‘liberal’ and ‘conservative’ meant.
People who are
most active in politics tend to have strong hooligan characteristics, notes
Jason Brennan (Against Democracy, pp 41 – 42). Diana
Mutz calls exposure to contrary points of view, or talking to people who
disagree ‘crosscutting political exposure’. Crosscutting political exposure
strongly decreases the likelihood that a person will vote, reduces the number
of political activities a person engages in, and makes people take longer to
decide how to vote. Conversely, people who have little crosscutting political
exposure tend to be the most active in politics and spend the most time in echo
chambers.
Social
psychologists
Jeremy A. Frimera, Linda J. Skitkab, and Matt Motyl have performed
experiments to understand people’s aversion to facts. The majority of people on
both sides of the same-sex marriage debate willingly gave up a chance to win
money to avoid hearing from the other side. Audi alteram partem may be a sound
legal maxim, but in ideological disagreements the injunction is routinely
flouted: Audi non alteram partem. “Their [participants’] lack of interest was
not due to already being informed about the other side or attributable election
fatigue. Rather, people on both sides indicated that they anticipated that hearing
from the other side would induce cognitive dissonance (e.g., require effort,
cause frustration) and undermine a sense of shared reality with the person
expressing disparate views (e.g., damage the relationship).”
The following
summarises the key features of irrationality:
Confirmation and Disconfirmation Bias We tend to accept
evidence that supports our preexisting views. We tend to reject or ignore evidence
that disconfirms our preexisting views.
Motivated Reasoning We have preferences over what we believe, and tend to
arrive at and maintain beliefs we find comforting or pleasing.
Intergroup Bias We tend to form coalitions or groups. We tend to
demonise members of other groups, but are highly forgiving and charitable
toward members of our own groups. We go along with whatever our group thinks
and oppose what other groups think.
Availability Bias The easier it is for us to think of something, the
more common we think that thing is, such as terrorism or a shark attack,
according to psychologists Daniel Kahneman and Amos Tversky. We are terrible at
probability and statistical reasoning. (Christopher
Achen and Larry Bartels recount how people in New Jersey were significantly
less likely to vote to re-elect President Woodrow Wilson in 1916 if they lived
near the sites of recent shark attacks.)
Prior attitude effect When we care strongly about an
issue, we evaluate arguments about the issue is a more polarised way.
Peer Pressure and Authority People tend to be
influenced irrationally by perceived authority, social pressure, and
conformity, as seen in the experiments by Muzafer Sherif, Solomon Asch and
Stanley Milgram (Against Democracy, pp 61 – 62).
We have seen at
great length that people are ignorant, misinformed and irrational. “In general,
the lower the epistemic and moral quality of an electorate, the worse
governmental policies will tend to be. Whom the voters select as a leader does
make a significant difference (Against Democracy, p 161)”.
Bangladesh is no
exception to the rule. The people’s choice of Sheikh Mujib turned out to be a
lemon. The socialist utopia he promised morphed into a nightmare. In addition,
when a famine occurred in 1974 (in which, on one estimate, 1.5
million people died), the government stood by, a spectator, even though
there was enough food in the country but it was exported to India (famine, Encyclopaedia
Britannica, 15th edition, 1988). A massive case of government
failure had occurred (giving the lie to Amartya
Sen’s contention that democracies never experience famine.) The
government estimated a death toll of 26,000, when, according to the Banglapedia, over
a million people died between July 1974 to January 1975.
It was in 1974
that Fr. Richard William Timm, watching a woman fighting off dogs for food in a
dustbin, decided to start a feeding program at Notre Dame College. Every day,
the padres fed a thousand people whom they saved from starvation.
To cut a long
story short, I will let Lawrence Ziring say it in his terse style:
"Mujib
presided over a court corrupted by power. It acted as though it could shelter
itself from the realities of Bangladesh. But the license that might have been
ignored in some other societies, could not be ignored in a country overrun by
self-styled enforcers, gouged by profiteers, and raped by government officials.
With literally hundreds and thousands dying from hunger, with millions more
threatened, high living in Bangladesh could only be equated with debauchery and
hedonism, with irresponsibility and indifference. To anyone with a grudge or a
sense of national purpose, the conclusion was the same. Deliberate efforts had
to be made to reverse course, and the only option for such a reversal lay with
a new team, and the only team capable of making the manoeuvre was the
Bangladesh army (Bangladesh: From Sheikh Mujib to Ershad: An Interpretive Study
(Dhaka, Bangladesh: University Press Limited, 1994, p 103)."
Mujib was in jail
in what was then West Pakistan, but returned to a hero's welcome to become
prime minister in January 1972 of his newly-created Bangladesh (formerly East
Pakistan). "Mujib believed he was Bangladesh, more so that he was good for
the country and that it could not manage without him. Those who reinforced
Mujib's impression of himself and his role did so because it benefited them
politically or materially, not because they truly believed in his leadership
(p. 93)." Yet, in the election of 1973, he won a landslide victory: the
disillusionment was still to come.
Mujib,
distrustful of the army, formed his own personal army, the Jatiyo Rakhi Bahini,
or National Security Force. "Opinion was strong that the paramilitary
organization was no different from Hitler's Brown Shirts or the Gestapo (p 98)."
The Rakhi Bahini unleashed a wave of terror and murder, along with other
anarchic groups. By 1974, several thousand politicians had paid for their lives
for defying or supporting Mujib.
Then, as we have
seen, in the summer of 1974, famine struck, and Mujib did not lift a finger to
help his Bengali followers.
Viewing the
decline of their creator's popularity, the Rakhi Bahini turned, not exactly on
Mujib, but on his followers. By the end of 1974, four thousand Awami Leaguers
were believed to have been murdered, including five ministers. Mujib then
belatedly distanced himself from the Rakhi Bahini, and called in the regular
army to restore a semblance of order. This exposed the army to the full extent
of the national problem.
On 28th
December, Mujib declared a state of emergency. He put the constitution aside,
abandoning the three-year old document as a legacy of colonial rule. The Awami
League was swept away by its leader.
In January 1975,
Mujib had himself declared president. "Mujib, not the Bangladesh army, had
removed the constraints on the arbitrary uses of power (p 102)."
BAKSAL, Mujib's
expression of the one-party state, was to take the place of the Awami League.
"Thus in a more significant way, BAKSAL was meant to serve the purpose of
the Bangabandhu's [literally, friend of the Bengalis, an honorific bestowed by devotees]
personal dictatorship, not the cause of national development and unity. BAKSAL
was proof positive that Mujib intended to convert the country into a personal
fiefdom for himself and his family members, and his many detractors did not
need convincing that their once respected leader, not they, was the real threat
to the nation's 'democratic' future (p 105)."
On 15th
August, 1975, a group of army officers stormed into Mujib's residence and
killed him and his entire family, with the fateful exception of his daughters
Sheikh Hasina and Sheikh Rehana, who were out of the country (in this, they
were backed, it was widely believed, by the CIA, according to Ayesha Jalal (p
89)).
Today, Sheikh
Hasina is prime minister of Bangladesh, and leader of the Awami League.
This turn of
events seems surprising, but it would appear that, in South Asia as a whole, it
is to be expected: here, failure pays. Ayesha Jalal has documented the
prevalence of authoritarianism alongside democracy in South Asia, but she never
mentions what did not happen rather
than what did. Often the dog that doesn’t bark is more telling than the dog
that does. India was defeated in the six weeks’ war with China in October –
November, 1962. Prime minister Jawaharlal Nehru didn’t resign, and nobody even
asked him to resign. In the opinion of Nehru’s biographer, Michael Edwards: “It
is a tribute to Nehru’s towering position both in the Congress and the country
that he neither suggested that he should resign nor was his resignation ever
called for – even by the opposition. It is difficult to believe that in any
other democratic state he and his cabinet could have survived (Nehru: A
Political Biography (Harmondsworth: Pelican, 1973), p 314)”. On the contrary,
his dynasty began with his only daughter, Indira Gandhi, after a brief
interval. In the words of Hugh Tinker: “That she had less than two years’
experience of Parliament and of cabinet office did not matter. She had the
mystique of the dead leader in her features and in her blood. Once again, the
past exerted its power over the future (South Asia: A Short History (London:
Pall Mall Press, 1966), p 243)”. Indira and her unelected son, Sanjay,
orchestrated the sterilization of nearly eleven million people (Percival Spear,
A History of India, Volume 2, (New Delhi: Penguin Books, 1990), pp 267 – 268)).
She paid a political price for her and her son’s actions, but only briefly. Her
career ended when she was gunned down by her Sikh guards. According to Stanley
J. Tambiah: “Even when the suddenness and the emotional trauma of Indira
Gandhi’s assassination are taken into account, the evidence is clear that...the
destructive actions of the mob...were encouraged, directed, and even
provisioned by Congress (I) politicians, activists and supporters, and
indirectly aided by an inactive, cooperative police force (Stanley J. Tambiah, Leveling
Crowds: Ethnonationalist Conflicts and Collective Violence in South Asia (New
Delhi: Vistaar Publications, 1997), p 137).” Her son, Rajiv Gandhi, became
premier, until he too was assassinated by Tamil terrorists (Sanjay had died in
1980). And for a while, it seemed that India would have an Italian-born,
ex-Catholic woman as prime minister, Rajiv’s widow, Sonia Gandhi. She was
elected from her husband’s constituency in Amethi, Uttar Pradesh. In 2017 Sonia
retired as head of the Congress Party and was succeeded by her son, Rahul.
One of the architects
of the destruction of the Babri
Mosque in December, 1992 was L K Advani. The breaking of the
mosque triggered riots in which an estimated 1,000 people died. He became home
minister (twice) and then deputy prime minister. About the
state elections in Gujarat in 2002, Kuldip Nayar, an Indian columnist, pointed
out that Chief Minister of Gujarat Narendra Modi “did best in the area where he
planned and executed ethnic cleansing” – a swing of 18 per cent in central
Gujarat and 11 per cent in the north. Altogether, the BJP won 126 seats in the
182-member assembly (The Daily Star, December 19, 2002). The Bush
administration refused him a visa, blaming him for the pogrom in which 2,000
Muslims were killed, according to The
Economist. “He may be a mass murderer,” opined Vir Sanghvi in
the Hindustan Times, the newspaper he edits, “but he's our mass murderer.” This
was a common reaction among Indians to the Bush administration’s decision. We
have seen the role of intergroup bias, in which we are forgiving of our own
group’s shortcomings and scathing about the outgroup’s misdeeds. Today,
Narendra Modi is India’s prime minister.
In Pakistan, this
sort of rabble-rousing has been almost absent, largely because the military has
run the country for most of its existence. However, failed leadership pays off
in Pakistan, too. Zulfiqar Ali Bhutto, the demagogue mentioned earlier, was
president and then prime minister of the country, despite being commonly
credited with the dismemberment of Pakistan. Bhutto was executed in 1979, but
his daughter, Benazir Bhutto succeeded in being premier two times. Benazir was assassinated
in 2007 (her brother had been killed by the police in 1996). Her son, Bilawal
Bhutto-Zardari, became chairman of his mother’s political party, the Pakistan
People’s Party, with Asif Ali Zardari, his father, being co-chairman.
At this point we
should note that in his book Leveling Crowds: Ethnonationalist Conflicts and
Collective Violence in South Asia, anthropologist Stanley J. Tambiah
establishes how democracy and ethnonationalist violence are causally connected
in the whole of South Asia. From the Sinhalese-Tamil riots of 1956 to 1983, to
the 1984 riots in Delhi and the post-Babri Masjid one, the author establishes
that ‘...participatory democracy, competitive elections, mass militancy, and
crowd violence are not disconnected (New Delhi: Vistaar Publications, 1997), p
260).” He goes so far as to affirm that “ethnonationalist conflicts combined
with collective violence are not just isolated volcanic eruptions but are close
to becoming systematized social formations. The evidence for the ritualized and
routinized forms of conduct that comprise a repertoire of collective violence
supports this assertion. In South Asia (and in many other places as well),
violence is an integral part of the political process (p 328).”
The election of
toxic leaders should not be hard to understand, for, we saw earlier, the
quality of the electorate determines the quality of the candidates. We have
seen that the electorate is ignorant, irrational and misinformed. Add to that
the fact that it is woefully uneducated in South Asia, and one isn’t surprised
to learn, for example, that there are 4,122 criminal cases against
current and former elected representatives in Parliament
and state legislatures in India (Daily Star, December 5, 2018).
The use of thugs
in Indian politics is wide-spread, acknowledged and accepted.
Take the world’s
largest volunteer organization, the Rashtriya Swayamsevak Sangh (RSS), an
epitome of civil society. Founded in 1925, the flagship of Hindutva today has
an all-male membership of 5 million. Narendra Modi, the prime minister of
India, served as an RSS pracharak (a
member of a hard core of RSS apostles). According to The
Economist: “Some RSS groups exercise quiet influence, lobbying
for more “nationalist” economic policy, for instance. Others simply wield
muscle. The 2m-member Bajrang Dal, a youth branch of the World Hindu Council,
an RSS offshoot, has a reputation for beating up Muslim boys who dare to flirt
with Hindu girls. The 3m-strong All India Students Council is aggressive in campus
politics. By threat or violent action it frequently blocks events it does not
like, such as lectures by secular intellectuals. Just outside the orbit of the
RSS lie violent extremist groups, such as one believed responsible for
murdering leftist writers.”
At the state
level, take Mamata
Banerjee, Chief Minister of West Bengal, and her Trinamool
Congress party. The TMC machine, which critics say is backed in many areas by
local criminal gangs, wields an intimidating presence in a state that has long
been coloured by political violence. It is often said that whoever controls the
ballot box controls the election. It does not help that the state police are
seen as subservient to the party. Tales of corruption and extortion under the
TMC are rife, and criminality by TMC street thugs has turned poor voters
against the the party. Before the election of 2016, aware of West Bengal’s
propensity for politically motivated violence, India’s national election
commission took vigorous steps. Besides staggering the votes over several
weeks, it replaced local police chiefs and election officials with its own
functionaries, mounted mobile and stationary patrols and rounded up suspected
thugs. Consequently, the election was
the most peaceful in West Bengal’s recent memory. Ms. Banerjee was not pleased.
(Nor was the previous lot saintly: after the crushing defeat of the
communist-led Left Front – in power for 34 years – in 2011, much of its street
muscle went over to Ms. Banerjee.)
When Uber
and Ola drivers went on strike last year in Mumbai, the strike was
rendered highly effective by the strength of powerful unions, in particular one
called Maharashtra Rajya Rashtriya Kamgar Sangh. Thousands would have crossed
picket lines but for their colleagues who maintained solidarity by, for
example, forcing strikebreakers to strip naked or by smashing their phones.
Dozens trying to work were beaten up and their cars damaged.
According to the World
Bank, enrollment in primary schools in South Asia rose
from 75 to 89 percent between 2000 and 2010, but the teaching has been of poor
quality. In Bangladesh, a survey
conducted by World Vision found that 54% of students in grade three do not
understand what they are reading, and 33% cannot read five words in thirty
seconds. In
India, 38% of Grade 3 children in government schools cannot
read simple words, and only 27% can do double-digit subtraction. More than half
of those in Grade 5 cannot read at Grade 2 level. Even when teachers show up
for class (and they often don’t) they are lacking in ability. “In India,
we need 9m teachers, but we don’t have 9m people who can teach,” says Pranab Kothari of Mindspark, an interactive software
developed in India to teach pupils.
During peaceful
protests by school children demanding safe roads and university students
demanding a more meritocratic public service exam, both groups, including
journalists, were beaten up by thumotic student thugs of the ruling Awami
League – and their pictures and names were published in newspapers and on the
internet by, for instance, Channel 4 in Violence, Abuse
and Disappearances in Bangladesh. One university protester was beaten
with a hammer before the cameras; two bones of his right leg were
broken, there were eight stitches on his head and bruises all over his body. He
was hounded from hospital to hospital (The Daily Star, July 5, 2018).
(The protesting
students were perceived as disobedient and their tormentors as obedient, to the
government. Disobedience, perceived or real, carries enormous costs in society,
not only in Bangladesh, but in South Asia. Louis Dumont, in his book Homo
hierarchicus (1970) has suggested that Indians be described by that expression
rather than by Homo aequalis, the western, individualistic type (Philip K.
Bock, Continuities in Psychological Anthropology (San Francisco, W H Freeman
and Company, 1980), p 128).
Despite these
incidents fresh in the memory, despite the extrajudicial killings, despite the
disappearances, despite the publication of former Chief Justice Sinha’s tell-all book, A Broken Dream, a staggering 62 percent of the people felt that the country was
headed in the right direction, according to a survey by the
International Republican Institute; and CallReady polled 1,186
young people and found that more than 51 percent wanted the
current government to stay in power.
The quality of
the electorate, according to historian Norman Davies, lay behind the rise of
Hitler and Nazism in Germany. “Hitler’s democratic triumph exposed the true
nature of democracy,” he affirms. “Democracy has few values of its own: it is
as good, or as bad, as the principles of the people who operate it. In the
hands of liberal and tolerant people, it will produce a liberal and tolerant
government: in the hands of cannibals, a government of cannibals. In Germany in
1933-4, it produced a Nazi government because the prevailing culture of
Germany’s voters did not give priority to the exclusion of gangsters (Europe: A
History (New York: Oxford University Press, 1996), p. 969).” This view is
shared by Jason Brennan (Against Democracy, p 159).
German fascism,
unlike fascism elsewhere, as in Italy, was not an elite product (Niall Ferguson,
The War of the World: Twentieth Century Conflict and The Descent of the West, (New
York: Penguin, 2006), p 240). However, a section of the elite warmed to Hitler,
where others he left cold. “The key to the strength and dynamism of the Third
Reich was Hitler’s appeal to the much more numerous intellectual elite; the men
with university degrees who are so vital for the smooth running of a modern
state and civil society.” Germany had the best universities in the world. More
than a quarter of the Nobel Prizes in the sciences between 1901 and 1940 were
awarded to Germans; only 11 percent went to Americans (p 235).
Heine anticipated
Nazism a hundred years earlier. “There will be,” he said in Religion and
Philosophy in Germany (1834), “Kantians forthcoming who in the new world to
come will know nothing of reverence for aught, and who will ravage without
mercy, and riot with sword and axe through the soil of all European life to dig
out the last root of the past; there will be well-weaponed Fichteans on the
ground, who in the fanaticism of the Will, are not to be restrained by fear or
self-advantage, for they live in the Spirit (quoted, Elie Kedourie, Nationalism
(London: Hutchinson & Co Ltd, 1969), p 89).” The German intellectual of the
1930s had a long pedigree.
The European
elite as a whole has learnt the lessons of history. When Jorg Haider’s Austrian
Freedom Party was elected with 27% of votes in 2000, it formed a coalition with
the centre-right People’s Party. Louis
Michel, Belgium’s foreign minister, called Haider a Nazi. “A man who
exults in Nazi theses is a Nazi,” said the minister. He observed that voters
can be “naive” and “simple”, that to be a democratic party “you must work by
democratic rules, you must accept not to play on the worst feelings each human
being has inside himself”. Hitler’s party also rose by democratic means. The
Freedom Party resembled the anti-immigrant and xenophobic Vlaams [Flemish]
Block. “I have forced all the democratic parties in Belgium to declare that
they will not do deals with Vlaams Blok,” he said.
This is a dispositionist
view: human beings have terrible feelings bottled up inside them, and leaders
can prey on these feelings. However, for Zimbardo, the situationist, the
‘barrel-makers’ constitute the system, which produces the bad barrel/situation,
occasioning the ‘bad apples’. In his book, he says “The power of charismatic
tyrannical leaders, like Jim Jones or Adolf Hitler, endures even after they do
terrible things to their followers, and even after their demise (p 295)”. In
other words, the evil that men do lives after them.
Before the
American presidential primary of 2016, the
Economist agonized over the impending choice of Donald Trump as
the Republican candidate. It fondly recalled that in 2002, France’s left and
right joined together to elect the unprincipled machine politician Jacques
Chiraq against his rival, Jean-Marie Le Pen, “a brutish demagogue”. Chirac owed
his victory not to his traditional supporters, but to his traditional left-wing
opponents. Posters urging the French to “Vote for the crook, not the fascist”
popped up across the country.
Since then, the
centre-left and centre-right have cooperated against the populist parties’
rising vote share in Finland, Italy, the Netherlands and Sweden (as of 2015,
according to the
Economist).
This is elitism,
pure and simple, or even paternalism. That the electorate of South Asia is not
educated cannot be a sufficient explanation for their choice of toxic rulers. The
American electorate is very well-educated, and the German intellectuals were
some of the most educated people in the world. The role of the elite, an
intermediate crust between the leader and the people, requires investigation,
for we have seen the European elite bandying together against wicked forces.
However, the role of education cannot totally be discounted, for it is
‘learning and wisdom’, to use Plato’s phrase, that transform the masses into an
elite.
Again, France
furnishes a clear example. Voting intentions in 2015 reveal that those with
less than high school education (36%) aimed to vote for the far-right,
xenophobic, nationalist, anti-European Union National Front; this share dropped
to 23% for those with a two-year degree and to 14% for those with a three-year
degree or more; the last group planned to vote much more for left-wing parties
(44%) and the centre-right (39%). This
shows the triumph of education over ignorance.
(Paternalism has
staged a remarkable comeback, not only in politics, but also in economics,
where the ‘rational individual’ had been solidly enshrined. In his book, Misbehaving:
The Making of Behavioural Economics (Penguin, 2016), Richard H. Thaler divides
people into ‘Econs’ and ‘Humans’, the former the nonexistent creature of
economic theory, and the latter the flesh-and-blood individuals of real life. Along
with a colleague, he was able to persuade people in one experiment to save more
than they were doing. An Econ would always be saving the right amount, being
perfectly rational. But Humans have problems such as inertia, loss aversion and
lack of self-control. When an economist of the traditional school evaluated
their experiment, he asked, “But, isn’t this paternalism? (pp 309 – 322)” This
was cruel, so they decided to call their version ‘libertarian paternalism’, or
nudge (the title of Thaler’s bestseller.)
So far, we have
investigated the lowest rung of the political ladder – the voter – and found
him/her clearly guilty. But did the elite also take part in the murder of
Mahima? Let us proceed.
According to
Finer, the Forum polity (democracy, republic) has been a rarity in history
whereas the Palace polity (monarchy) and its variants have been the most
common. Only in the last two centuries has it become more widespread.
Historically, it was largely restricted to the Greek poleis, the Roman Republic, and the mediaeval European
city-states.
He adds, however:
“Furthermore, most of them for most of the time exhibited the worst
pathological features of this kind of polity. For rhetoric read demagogy, for
persuasion read corruption, pressure, intimidation, and falsification of the
vote. For meetings and assemblies, read tumult and riot. For mature
deliberation through a set of revising institutions, read instead
self-division, inconstancy, slowness, and legislative and administrative
stultification. And for elections read factional plots and intrigues. These
features were the ones characteristically associated with the Forum polity in
Europe down to very recent times. They were what gave the term ‘Republic’ a bad
name, but made ‘Democracy’ an object of sheer horror. (The History of
Government, pp. 46-47).” As we have seen, Polybius identified democracy with
ochlocracy, and even in the eighteenth century it continued to be a pejorative.
Thus, when
Tambiah identifies democracy as the cause of violence in South Asia, we should
not be surprised. “The general theme of whether democracy as a political
process and the democratic state as a system intensify the occurrence of
violence is an old one in the history of political theory. From the Greeks
onwards, even up to the nineteenth century, many theorists, perhaps most,
associated democracy with civil strife, and it is only subsequently that this
became a minority view (Levelling Crowds, p 262).”
The minority view
is not held by the elite of Bangladesh (or of South Asia). Why do they persist
in believing in a system that is shown to be dangerous by empirical evidence?
There are two reasons for this tenacity: one rational, another irrational.
First, the
irrational.
The psychology of
an elite has deep roots in experience, not so much immediate, but distant, as
is history. We have seen outgroup-ingroup hostility and favoritism at work (in
the context of Bangladesh, what West Pakistan did to ‘us’ is beyond criminal,
but what ‘we’ did to ourselves, as in the famine of 1974 and other events of
the period, must not be discussed; in India, Narendra Modi may be a ‘mass
murderer’ but he’s ‘our’ mass murderer, and so on.) However, society at any
given time consists of groups that dominate other groups. Heavily influenced by
evolutionary psychology, the group
dominance theory, chiefly associated with Jim Sidanius and his colleagues,
views society as inherently oppressive and group oppression to be the “normal,
default, condition of human relations” (Political Psychology, p 174 – 175). Sidanius argues that
“most forms of
oppression including racism, ethnocentrism (including the oppression of
religious minorities such as Jews) sexism, nationalism, and classism and as
well as a number of other social attitudes, human drives and social
institutions function, in part, to help establish and maintain the integrity of
this group-based hierarchical structure.”
An interesting
corollary to this theory is the notion of outgroup
favouritism. Outgroup favouritism or deference occurs among lower-status
groups in relation to higher-status ones. Sidanius’ example is that of Uncle
Tomming by blacks towards whites in the segregation era. A Scottish observer
said of freed slaves that “chains of a stronger kind still manacled their
limbs, from which no legislative act could free them; a mental and moral
subordination and inferiority to which tyrant custom has here subjected all the
sons and daughters of Africa (Scott Christianson, With Liberty for Some: 500
Years of Imprisonment in America, (Boston: Northeastern University Press,
1998), p 142 – 143).” Lower-status groups may also under-achieve due to lower
social expectations.
The corresponding
example from South Asia may be Dr
Azizzing after the fictitious character Dr. Aziz in E M Forster’s A Passage
to India (1924).
Pherozeshah
Mehta, one of the early graduates from the University of Bombay, speaking in
1867, drew attention to “the strong Anglicising undercurrent which has begun through
the deeper instincts of Indian students”. With pride, he predicted: “There will
ere long be produced in India a body of men out-Heroding Herod, more English
than the English themselves”. The instrument was English-language education. In
1860, there were 40,366 students in the schools of Bengal receiving an
English-language education; in Madras Presidency, the number was 6,552 and in
Bombay, 2,984. The number of university graduates in Bengal, Madras and Bombay in 1864
were, respectively, 28, 11 and 8; in 1885, the corresponding figures were 264,
163 and 72 (South Asia, pp 180 – 181). My late uncle went to Presidency College
in Calcutta, where he once blurted out a few words in Bengali for which he
received a severe reprimand from the teacher: English was the intra-mural
language!
In 1882, the
headquarters of the Theosophical Society was moved from New York to Adyyar near
Madras. For a brief period, Madame Blavatsky, a co-founder, lived in India.
Speaking at Banaras, she said: “If the modern Hindus were less sycophantic to
their Western masters, less in love with their vices, and more like their
ancestors”, they would acquire mastery, through occult power (South Asia, p
182).
“In any town in
India,” writes George Orwell in Burmese
Days (1934), “the European Club is the spiritual citadel,
the real seat of the British power, the Nirvana for which native officials and
millionaires pine in vain. It was doubly so in this case, for it was the proud
boast of Kyauktada Club that, almost alone of Clubs in Burma, it had never admitted
an Oriental to membership.” Thus, Orwell gives brick-and-mortar shape to the
psychology of the ruler-ruled relationship that was the Raj, where a couple of
hundred thousand British soldiers controlled teeming millions.
Dr. Veraswami
befriends our anti-hero, Flory, and urges the latter to let him join the Club
to escape the machinations of U Po Kyin, Sub-divisional Magistrate of Kyauktada.
“And you do not
know what prestige it gives to an Indian to be a member of the European
Club. In the Club, practically he iss a European,” observes the good
doctor. The members naturally object to having a ‘nigger’ in their midst. “He's
asking us to break all our rules and take a dear little nigger-boy into this
Club.”
Dr. Veraswami’s
admiration for the British is pathetic. “Dr Veraswami had a passionate
admiration for the English, which a thousand snubs from Englishmen had not
shaken. He would maintain with positive
eagerness that he, as an Indian, belonged to an inferior and degenerate race.” Flory and the doctor have a regularly comic conversation,
in which the Englishman knocks down the English and Veraswami defends them. Dr.
Veraswami says: “'My friend, my friend, you are forgetting the Oriental
character. How iss it possible to have developed us, with our apathy and
superstition? At least you have brought
to us law and order. The unswerving British Justice and the Pax Britannica.”
The frankest
expression of cultural cringe –as we may call this type of outgroup favouritism
- flowed from the pen of Nirad C.
Chaudhuri, who favoured all things British against all things Indian: “...all
that was good and living within us was made, shaped and quickened by the same
British rule (quoted, Mark Tully, No Full Stops In India (New Delhi: Penguin
Books, 1993), p 57).”
Swami Dayananda,
founder of the Arya Samaj (Society of Arians) in Bombay, in 1875, famously
tried to show that all Western scientific knowledge had been revealed in the
Vedas – telecommunications, ships, aircraft, gravity and gravitational
attraction (Peter Van Der Veer, Imperial Encounters (Delhi: Permanent Black,
2006), p 50).
The South Asian
elite are in a parlous state. Spare a thought for Martin Kampchen, who wrote
from Santiniketan: “Several daily newspapers of Calcutta flashed the news of
Jhumpa Lahiri’s wedding in Calcutta as their first-page leader, complete with a
colourful photo of the happy couple. First I thought: O happy Bengal! You still
honour your poets as the ancient civilisations used to do. And for a moment I
remained in this innocent bliss of satisfaction. Then it dawned on me that not
any writer’s marriage is accorded such flattering coverage. Only expatriates
who have ‘made it good’ abroad, who have ‘done the country proud’, are subjected
to such exaggerated honours (The Daily Star, 27th January, 2001).” Jhumpa Lahiri had just won the Pulitzer for
her collection of short stories, The Interpreter of Maladies.
Before he became
prime minister of Pakistan, Imran Khan used to insult some people by calling
them Brown Sahibs (maybe he still does). Most of his friends fit that
description – which means they ape the dress, habits and affectations of the
former British colonial masters. Indeed, Khan himself used very much to be a
Brown Sahib. “His English is more polished than his Punjabi,” according to the Independent.
A pejorative
expression used by South Asians for South Asians is ‘coconut’: brown outside,
white inside.
In 2006, a photo
of then prime minister Khaleda Zia taken by Shahidul Alam was printed on the
cover of TIME magazine. The Daily Star, the leading English daily of
Bangladesh, made a point of mentioning the fact in its pages (April 14, 2006):
“We would also like to take this opportunity to commend Mr. Alam for being the
first Bangladeshi photographer whose work has been featured on the cover of
Time magazine.” Alam had ‘made it’ in the west, so he had to be ‘honoured’.
“You mention the
name Bangladesh to a westerner and wait for his or her first reaction and what
you hear may not please your ear” lamented the now-defunct English daily The
Bangladesh Observer in its cover story (October 20th, 2006). But all
is not lost! Mohammed Yunus and his Grameen Bank had won the Nobel Peace Prize,
rekindling “the (sic) Bengali nationalism in the teeming millions”. Never mind
that a connection, however tenuous, between a Nobel Prize for microcredit and
Bengali nationalism, is not immediately obvious. The former, conferred by the
outgroup, raises the prestige of the latter.
James Fenimore
Cooper (1789-1851), the first American novelist, knew all about cultural
cringe, and was probably the first person to articulate the phenomenon of
cultural imperialism. Consider this footnote from his novel Afloat and Ashore
(1844):
‘The miserable
moral dependence of this country on Great Britain, forty years since, cannot
well be brought home to the present generation. It is still too great, but has
not a tithe of its former force. The writer has himself known an Italian
prince, a man of family and high personal merit, pass unnoticed before a
society that was eager to make the acquaintance of most of the agents of the
Birmingham button dealers; and this simply because one came from Italy and the
other from England....(Afloat and ashore, a sea tale (New York, Hurd and
Houghton, 1871), p 439n).”
Despite the fact
of American independence, the reality was that Americans still suffered from a
colonial mentality. His book had been ‘puffed’ in England, which gave it
greater mystique in America.
A more recent
case of cultural cringe has been detected down under. In fact, the term has
been coined to cover the feeling that Australia is only a reflection of the
mother country. In “The Lucky Country” (1964), Donald Horne famously suggested
focus on Asia as an alternative to the “sometimes humiliating attempts to keep
up the family relationship with Europeans…It is in dealings with Asian
countries that Australians might regain a sense of confidence and importance” (Quoted
in The Economist, December 14th, 1996, ‘Australia’s Identity Crisis’, pp 35-37).
In the ensuing brouhaha, the thought got buried in static. Nevertheless, Paul
Keating went down in history as the man who suggested ingratiatingly in Singapore
that ‘mateship’ was an Asian value!
Parents in
Bangladesh proudly announce that their children live in Britain, America,
Canada or Australia. Living in the Middle East just doesn’t cut it. As an
English teacher, I can vouch for the fact that those fluent in English positively
look down on those lacking English. One of my former students said that she
hated English medium students who proudly say they are weak in Bengali, the mother
tongue. And this despite years of Bengali nationalism – Bengalism – when
teaching in English was prohibited up to the age of 16. Father Peixotto, an
American, delivered his physics lectures at Notre Dame College in the 1970s in
Bengali, despite complaints from the students that he couldn’t be understood.
He insisted he was required by law to lecture in Bengali. All that is over, of
course. English medium schools have spawned all over the country. On YouTube,
young people in intimate talk shows such as this one with D J
Sonica combine fluent English with Bengali, which is
considered ‘cool’ (modern).
‘The return of
the repressed’, in Freudian language, refers to the tendency of repressed
psychic material to reemerge in the life of an individual – or society
(Continuations in Anthropological Psychology, p 165). Thus, in Europe ‘the
spectre of communism’ and, today, fascism and, in America, racism, and
anti-Semitism in both have resurfaced to bedevil society. In Bangladesh, the
repression of Islam under Sheikh Mujib was reversed by General Zia; the
repression of the love of English never quite succeeded in pushing it below the
surface, and has come into its own in full daylight.
The people speak
Bengali, which they can barely read. The elite are drawn to English. The two
never meet (except during elections). Tambiah remarks: ““In India, Pakistan,
Sri Lanka, and Bangladesh, the attempt to realise the nation-state on a Western
European model has virtually failed. The nation-state conception has not taken
deep roots in South Asia or generated a wide-spread and robust participatory
‘public culture’ that celebrates it in widely meaningful ceremonies, festivals,
and rituals (Levelling Crowds, p 264)”.
It is not only
the nation concept that has failed, but the very notion of the state itself. The
focus on language in South Asia has dimmed all idea of the state. The raison d’etre of the state is salus populi – the safety of the people –
to use Hobbes’s expression. When a state fails to secure the people, they can
have no allegiance to it. Loyalty for protection is a rational exchange. Loyalty
to a language defies rationality. A language is not a determinate territory
over which the sovereign’s writ runs. A language, unlike a police force, cannot
protect citizens from violence. A language may be spread beyond the national
frontiers (as in the case of Bengali, which is spoken in West Bengal), or in a sub-region,
like the contesting languages of India, and, to a lesser extent, Pakistan. In
1952, just seven years after the independence of India, Potti Sreeramulu
starved himself to death for a Telugu state – within India. This was the
beginning of the linguistic ‘states’. It took a civil war in Sri Lanka to
settle a linguistic struggle.
“Nationalists,”
argues Kedourie, “must operate in a hazy region, midway between fable and
reality, in which states, frontiers, compacts are at once both real and unreal
(p 71)”. Compacts, that is, not only among states, but among citizens of the
same state, the social contract. (Kedourie finds no distinction between
linguistic, racial, cultural and religious nationalism (p 73), so his
observation would apply to India and Pakistan today.)
Thus, it is no
accident that the subcontinent has developed no concept of the state, and where
the state itself uses violence against its own citizens. Private armies, such
as those employed by Sheikh Mujib and Zulfiqar Ali Bhutto, and the impromptu
rabble roused by political parties in India, constitute states within the
state, as do the current private armies, the student thugs, of the two leaders
of Bangladesh.
This is the ‘Lord
of the Flies’ effect referred to above. Security is a public good that only the
state can provide; it cannot be bought in the marketplace. Ayesha Jalal, in her
book on South Asia, considers the state to have two functions (redistribution and
development), neither of which includes security, but assumes its presence. Consider
the daylight murder of Biswajit
Das. During a hartal conducted by the BNP, on December 9, 2012, members of
the ruling party student thugs, the Chatra League, suspecting Das to be an
opposition activist, hacked and beat him to death while the police stood by.
The 24-year-old Das was a tailor on the way to his shop in Laxmibazaar.
Pictures of Das in his bloodstained shirt trying to ward off the thugs were
published in all the newspapers
It is not the
function of a state to promote a language or a religion (not dissimilar) nor to
promote redistribution or development, these being second-order functions, but
to promote the safety of the people and the protection of their property.
Absent this public good, the state can never have a stab at the other goods of
redistribution and development.
But we have
digressed from the observation that everything to do with the white race
appears to us as remarkable. The belief that western civilisation is superior
to ours is deeply ingrained in the elite. We have relieved the white man of his
burden, and carry it on our shoulders. And the white man left us with a
democratic burden, which we carry like a cross.
Despite the
slaughter of the two world wars, despite the killings in Vietnam, despite the
murder of 1.7
million Iraqi children through sanctions, the bombing of Afghanistan and
Iraq, our respect for western civilisation remains undimmed. “The white race is
the cancer of history,” wrote Susan Sontag, but
we believe the white race to be the benefactor of humankind.
Let me begin my
overview of the media elite in Bangladesh with an autobiographical account. After
the democratic transition of 1990, I did some research and the output was an
essay called “Democracy: The Historical Accident”. I submitted the piece to the
highbrow English weekly, Holiday. The editor changed the title, saying it was
“too loud”.
Then I wrote an article
on the emergency of 1958 in Ceylon, which I called “The Devil And The Deep”.
The editor of the most widely circulated English daily, The Daily Star. Mahfuz
Anam, objected to the title. “The devil of democracy!” he gasped. “People want
democracy now.” The title was changed.
After a series of
violent hartals and murders, I concluded another article with the one-sentence
paragraph ‘We can have either democracy or safety, but not both’. The article
appeared in the Daily Star, but with the last paragraph expunged, and the
editor’s own words in its place, pleading for democracy.
My final and last
encounter with the Daily Star occurred when an editor, Modon Shahu, told me “We
know people want martial law, but we can’t print that”. If a newspaper knows
what the people want, but won’t say it, that’s self-censorship. (Strangely
enough, the motto of the Daily Star, blazoned across its online articles and
print issues, is ‘Committed to PEOPLE’S RIGHT TO KNOW).
But these are
mere peccadilloes compared to what the newspapers in Bangladesh got up to in
order to connive at fake elections.
A little
background first. As the reader will recall, General Ershad (always ‘General’)
resigned the presidency on December 6, 1990. Illegally, he was kept in jail
along with the vice president, Moudud Ahmed, who, by the constitution, was
supposed to assume the presidency on the incumbent’s resignation. Instead, the
Chief Justice of the Supreme Court, violated the constitution of which he was
chief protector, became president, without a murmur of protest from the
national as well as international community.
The first ‘free
and fair’ elections were held in 1991, and the Bangladesh Nationalist Party
(BNP) won, with Khaleda Zia as leader. The Awami League led by Sheikh Hasina
was now the opposition.
At the end of her
tenure, Khaleda Zia refused to budge and only a series of hartals, blockades
and sieges by the Awami League succeeded in removing her from office. A
Solomonic arrangement was arrived at: a neutral, caretaker government would
henceforth oversee all elections, and not the ruling party, which would step
down. (The advisor to the caretaker government would be the previous retired
Chief Justice of the Supreme Court – what this would mean for the independence
of the judiciary can be guessed at.)
Elections under
the neutral, caretaker government were held in 1996 and 2001, with the parties
rotating in power. The democratic miracle had been achieved – a two-party system,
with opposition and ruling party changing place every five years.
After the
election in 2001, a government officer told me confidentially that the election
had been bogus. I didn’t believe him.
Then, I read an
article in The
Economist and felt like a fool for disbelieving such a reliable
source. Now, our newspapers always report and even republish news items on
Bangladesh published in prestigious western journals like the New York Times,
the Washington Post, the Guardian, and, of course, the Economist.
Not a single word
appeared in the newspapers of Bangladesh about the findings of Walter Mebane
and his team at Cornell reported in the Economist. Mebane and others studied
the figures for the three elections in this country in 1991, 1996 and 2001. The
first was clean, the second showed that some 2% of results were problematic and
the third, a glaring 9%. Yet the elections had been vetted by the Carter Center
and the European Union.
The caretaker
government had been a ploy to provide the illusion of an alternation of power.
Its latent function – as opposed to
its manifest function of overseeing
true elections - was to ensure Buggins’ turn. Local as well as international
actors connived at the chimera. (The caretaker government was ditched after the
2008 election held under a military government. Since then, Bangladesh has been
a one-party state.)
The sentiments of
the elite were echoed by writer Tahmima Anam,
daughter of Mahfuz Anam, when she wrote for the BBC: “For three consecutive
elections, we have had a large and enthusiastic electorate who have ushered in
freely elected governments and representative parliaments. Although young and
sometimes faltering, we have been understandably proud of our fledgling
democracy.” Apparently, we, the people
of Bangladesh, are brains in vats being fed our stimuli by
malevolent/benevolent forces.
Do the elite have
extra-rational reasons for their faith in democracy? Yes, as we have seen.
However, they also have eminently rational reasons for pretending to have faith in the system.
For depth of
analysis, we will consider faith and pretended faith in the God that failed:
Communism.
In the early 1950s,
the Czech party member Zdenek Mlynar, then a student at Moscow University, was
accosted by a very drunk Russian. The latter had just voted in favour of
keeping out a friend from the party for a minor offence. Ashamed of himself, he
asked Mlynar to “call him a pig” (we know from Dostoyevsky how those Russians
are given to bouts of alternating criminality and contrition.) When Mlynar inquired why, he received the
following reply: “Because you are not a pig, you really believe in all
this...You read Lenin, even when you are all alone. You understand? You have
faith in all these ideas.” The Pig went on to become a successful military
prosecutor. In the late 1970s, Mlynar went on to write, “No doubt he still gets
drunk after a trial and gets someone to call him a pig” (Richard Vinen, A
History in Fragments: Europe in the Twentieth Century (Da Capo Press, 2001), p
424).
The children of
the nomenclatura grew up, pigs almost to the last man and woman. They cared
nothing for communism, and a great deal for their inherited privileges. As
communism became more manifestly a failure, the Believers – there were still
some – tried to reform the system. The Pigs made a show of ‘outward orthodoxy’,
to use Vinen’s expression, but were in fact concerned only with their careers.
Of course, the
Pigs twigged that capitalism would allow them to pass on their privileges
better, and that they were in a unique position to benefit from the transition
to capitalism. In the event, according to Vinen, the move to capitalism was a
‘management buyout’ (p 429). Some people lamented that self-interest, rather
than idealism, had won the day. Istvan Csurka of the Hungarian Democratic Forum
said that “his country had been cheated of the revolution” (p 432).
While the
communist threat remained alive, it was American foreign policy to promote
non-democratic rulers and strongmen in the Third World. We have seen that both
Sheikh Mujib and Zulfiquar Ali Bhutto appealed to the poor with their socialist
ideas to win elections. The CIA actions against Chile’s elected president
Salvador Allende constituted the end of the socialist wave that began in the
late 1960s, according to Ayesha Jalal (p 84). Both leaders were destined to be
killed by the army. General Ziaur Rahman came to power in 1977; he founded the
Bangladesh Nationalist Party (BNP) and reversed Mujib’s socialism and
nationalisation with a program of privatization and denationalisation, moving
the country firmly towards free markets and capitalism. He was killed by army personnel
in 1981. General Hussein Mohammad Ershad (1982 – 1990) continued the manoeuvre
to the right.
In the 1980s, Jeane
Kirkpatrick was perhaps Ronald Reagan’s most influential foreign policy
advisor. In her obituary, The
Economist observed that “she supported military interventions,
covert proxy wars, the coddling of anti-communist dictators and the
full-blooded, unapologetic pursuit of America's national interests”. America
had loss its confidence under Jimmy Carter; she felt no need to compromise or
apologise, coming out fighting against an ‘expansionist’ Soviet Union.
Her 1979 article
‘Dictatorship and Double Standards’ seethed with realism:
“No idea holds
greater sway in the mind of educated Americans than the belief that it is
possible to democratise governments, anytime and anywhere, under any
circumstances.” “Decades, if not centuries, are normally required for people to
acquire the necessary disciplines and habits. In Britain, the road [to
democratic government] took seven centuries to traverse.” “The speed with which
armies collapse, bureaucracies abdicate, and social structures dissolve once
the autocrat is removed frequently surprises American policymakers.”
When the Cold War
ended, the West reversed its policy: now it would champion democracy. The myth
was born that on December 6, 1990 General Ershad was forced to resign by the
thumotic student thugs of the political parties. The reality is more banal: The
General didn’t jump, he was pushed – by the western donors. With the collapse
of the Berlin Wall, the number of democracies in sub-Saharan Africa rose from 4
in 1989 to 33 in 1995 (The Economist, September 7th 1996, ‘Survey of Sub-Saharan
Africa’, p. 5). In the 1960s, 1970s and 1980s, only one sub-Saharan government
was peacefully voted out of office. ‘Now
nearly all face regular elections…’About this
epidemic of freedom, anthropologists Patrick Chabal and Jean-Pascal Daloz in
their book Africa Works: Disorder as Political Instrument (Oxford: James
Currey, 1999) says: “It cannot simply be a coincidence that, now that the West
ties aid to democratisation under the guise of multi-party elections,
multi-party elections are taking place in Africa (p 118).” And in Bangladesh. As The
Economist observed: “…the cold war's end prompted western
donors to stop propping up anti-communist dictators and to start insisting on
democratic reforms”. And it was only in 1991 in Harare, Zimbabwe that heads of
state declared that the Commonwealth
should promote democracy and human rights. “When the Commonwealth moves
collectively, that is, when all countries are pursuing the same objective of
free and fair elections and good governance, it can act against countries that
don’t even pay lip service to those values,” wrote Sir
Donald McKinnon, Commonwealth secretary-general 2000-2008. “The fact
that Zimbabwe and Gambia are no longer in the Commonwealth is because of a
reluctance by the leaders of those countries to accept, adhere, commit and
administer those values.” Apparently, Bangladesh at least pays “lip service” to
the values of the Commonwealth (and no more, as we shall see.).
Money that had
hitherto been channeled through the state now began to flow to non-state actors
– NGOs. Unsurprisingly, these have proliferated. Again, Chabal and Daloz make
an astute observation: “The political significance of such a massive
proliferation of NGOs in Africa deserves closer attention. Our research
suggests that this expansion is less the outcome of the increasing political
weight of civil society than the consequence of the very pragmatic realisation
that resources are now largely channeled through NGOs (p 22).” In other words,
a rational response to monetary rewards.
Between, 2000 and
2005, Bangladesh languished at the very bottom of Transparency
International’s Corruption Perception Index; in 2013, the World Bank
scrapped South Asia’s biggest foreign-funded infrastructure project, the Padma
bridge, because of corruption by Bangladeshi officials. It is naïve to argue that
there is corruption everywhere in Bangladesh except among NGOs. It has been
estimated by economist Abul Barkat that only 25% of donor money reaches the
poor in Bangladesh (New Nation, September 26, 2003); the remainder goes towards
meeting administrative costs, including salaries. Chabal and Daloz observe that
“...there is today an international ‘aid market’ which Africans know how to
play with great skill. Indeed, there is very little doubt that NGOs spend an
excessive proportion of their budget on furnishing their members with
sophisticated and expensive equipment (from computers to four-wheel drives),
leaving all too little for the development projects which justify the work of
the NGOs in the first place (p 23).” This observation can be made of Bangladesh
verbatim. Dr. Mozaffer
Ahmed, economist and former chairman of Transparency
International Bangladesh, echoed Abul Barkat when he observed that “Beneficiaries
get only 20 to 22 percent of the foreign funds while [the] rest are used as
‘cost of fund’ meaning house rent, salary and other expenses”. According to The Economist:
“There are about 20,000 non-governmental organisations (NGOs) in Bangladesh,
probably more than in any other country.”
Therefore, it is
not surprising that a BBC
survey found that every section of society was suspicious of
NGOs. Only three percent surveyed wanted to give them more power - and only two
per cent admired social work, the 'least admired' of all kinds of work.
I became quite
friendly with a top NGO honcho, and over dinner at a party, he gave me his job
description. “I’m supposed to speak well of the West, say how good it is….” He
had no illusions. Today, he lives in Baridhara, a posh enclave in Dhaka city.
Here is a
sprinkling of facts about the income of NGOs and their connection with
democracy. The reader should keep in mind the fact that the annual per
capita income in Bangladesh is $4,200 (on a purchasing power parity (PPP) basis).
24 local NGOs were given Takas 15 million - $260,000 – by USAID, DFID and the
Swiss Development Corporation to observe the elections in 2001(at the exchange
rate at the time). Another NGO – Association of Social Advancement – garnered
Takas 10m - $175,000 - to meet monitoring expenses alone (The Daily Star, July
25, 2001 and August 11, 2001). And, again to meet election monitoring costs,
the Coordination Council for Human Rights in Bangladesh received Takas 7.6m -
$133,000 - from ‘an institution in the Netherlands’ (The Bangladesh Observer,
April 5 2002). And Acting High Commissioner of Australia, Dr. Michele Forster,
handed over a cheque for Takas 405,000 to the Executive Director of Democracy
Watch, Ms. Taleya Rahman, for a Democracy Festival in northern Bangladesh (Observer,
March 16 2002). Before the local (Union Parishad) level elections of 2003, eight
NGOs were granted Takas 23,000,000 ($383,333) by the Danish aid agency DANIDA
to monitor the elections – and some familiar names and acronyms crop up, such
as, Democracy Watch, Bangladesh Manobadhikar Bastobayan Sangstha, ASA, NEOC,
MMC....( The Daily Star, January 21, 2003).
The manifest function of NGOs is to promote
civil society (as well as development); their latent function is to purchase the loyalty of the elite.
The total silence
of the NGOs and civil society in general on the subject of student thugs
killing each other over turf can be explained in terms of their eagerness to
please donors: the thugs are an integral part of the democratic process. If
they did not take to the streets (hartal), the ruling party would continue in
power.
People like
Tahmima Anam write for the BBC and the Guardian and,
I’m sure, other western publications. In the latter, she wrote that “I can
insist that the story of Bangladesh is not the story of a secular country that
has turned to radicalism: it is the story of a country that has, against all
odds, survived, even flourished.” Whether Bangladesh has flourished or not is
moot: statistics on Bangladesh are hard to find. But for my present purpose
that is neither here nor there. (When statistics are available, they are often
depressing; for instance, the official unemployment rate is an enviable 4.4%.
However, about
40% of the population is underemployed; many persons counted as employed
work only a few hours a week and at low wages. The only industry, the garments
sector, is incapable of absorbing these surplus workers. And the outlook for
even this one industry is gloomy as labour-replacing machines take the place of
unskilled workers.)
When I tried to
portray an unflattering picture of Bangladesh and its toxic leadership (which
is mentioned in neither the BBC nor the Guardian articles), I met with
resistance, at least, and indifference, at worst.
I recall writing
to New Hope International, and the editor sending me a terse note saying that
if I found democracy so deficient, what alternative did I propose? Earlier, the
chief editor had said that they would have been happier if I had attributed the
violence I described to the market-friendly policies of the World Bank and the
IMF!
I approached the
Christian Science Monitor – they weren't remotely interested. I wrote to The
Nation – thinking that this paper would surely be concerned about the plight of
teenage boys used as thugs by the political parties; I never even heard from
them.
I sent an article
to the New Statesman. I got a reply saying that the relevant editor would get
back to me after the Christmas holidays. I never heard from him again.
Then, my own
analysis told me what was going on – these major newspapers were part of what I
have come to call ‘The Freedom Industry’. Since their readers have been
indoctrinated into believing that democracy is God's gift to humanity (GeorgeBush's phrase), any criticism of democracy would not go down well with them.
Prestige and money were at stake.
Finally, I
learned about the Alternative Media/ Indy media.
My first ‘break’
came when Csaba Polony of Left Curve published a cycle of poems on the murder
of student politicians by student politicians. I was grateful: I realised that
criticism of students – who were supposed to have overthrown a dictator in 1990
– would only be acceptable to low-budget, low-circulation. non-mainstream
newspapers and magazines.
And that turned
out to be the case: I sent my article to an online journal called Axis of
Logic. The editor was breathless with excitement: he immediately published it,
and even tried to call me from America – but it wasn’t easy to get through to
Bangladesh. (The article is called The
Freedom Industry and Student Politics in Bangladesh.) As for the
fate of the present piece I’m working on, I’ll settle for the least reluctant
publisher anywhere in the world (except Bangladesh, where it’ll never see the
light of day, as experience has taught me).
The
intelligentsia to which people like Tahmima Anam belong (her mother, Shaheen
Anam, is executive director of the mega-NGO, Manusher Jonno (For the People),
which dispenses donor money to lesser NGOs), have extra-rational as well as
rational motives. To observe one extra-rational motive yet again, consider that
a lasting insult in Bangladesh is to call somebody “a Bangalee” (speaker of Bengali)
– the antithesis of a westerner, lacking in refinement, sophistication,
upbringing. Echoes of Macaulay, who
had some nasty things to say about Bengalis, reverberate even
today. This is a classic case of ‘outgroup favouritism’, Uncle Tomming or Dr.
Azizing, as we saw above.
Imagine, then,
what affirmation and rejection by the outgroup mean for the psychology of an
intellectual in Bangladesh. It is a commonplace in economics and business that
the customer is king, and in our case the customer is the West. But this
particular customer is a monopsonist – a single buyer – and has the power to
exploit. Liberals rail against colonial and neo-colonial exploitation, but is
shtum on this subject.
The result is anti-empiricism.
In her BBC
article, Tamima Anam continues, “Otherwise, even if the military cleans up the
political landscape, even if they arrest all the corrupt politicians, even if
they seize the illegal assets and raze the buildings that were made with black
money, who will become our new democratic leaders? Who will we be left to
believe in? Only those who wrested power in the first place: the army.” (She is
referring to the military takeover by General Moeen U Ahmed on January 11, 2007
when the caretaker arrangement came unglued and the country threatened to tear
itself apart in an orgy of violence and murder – which Ms. Anam keeps mum about
-under the two toxic leaders, who were later jailed, ending with elections in
December 2008 in which the old Awami League and its leader Sheikh Hasina won with
generous financial assistance from India. Delaying the
vote averted a possible bloodbath, observed
The Economist. Neither is she gratified that student thuggery
disappeared in 2007-8, the number of student thugs murdered falling to 10 and
8, from 48 in 2006 and rising to 27 in 2009 on the departure of the military in
December 2008. For some reason, the murder of these hapless boys, the hoplites
of democracy, does nor rouse any degree of grief or sympathy.) Note her lament:
“Who will be left to believe in?” This need for heroes has landed us with toxic
leaders, leaders who seem miraculously to have inherited heroism. It is about
time we stopped looking for heroes, and started trusting in our own finite
resources, talents and abilities. (Interestingly,
South
Africans, who can boast numerous heroes, do not believe that
heroism is inherited – or vice, for that matter.)
“If they do not
hand over power to elected leaders, they will emerge as the most powerful force
in Bangladeshi politics. And a victorious army, as history has taught us time
and again, is a dangerous thing.”
This is a common
refrain. Referring to the resignation of General Ershad in 1990, Ayesha Jalal
affirms that “In Bangladesh, an unpopular military regime was forced to pass
the mantle to a popularly elected government….(p 4)”. (Ershad is referred to as
a ‘despot’ in Time
magazine.)
General Zia and
General Ershad were military rulers – the first is considered a national hero
by followers, while, it is true, that the second was perceived as anti-hero
unable to rouse the thumos of student thugs.
These are the
facts about Ershad. He
was wrongly imprisoned by the caretaker government led by Chief Justice Shahabuddin Ahmed; his detention
was declared illegal by the Supreme Court in 1998; one of the judges was the
late B B Roy Chowdhury (who sternly disapproved of the Chief Justice being
president ultra vires of the constitution in a personal conversation with me);
the judgment, he told me, had for precedent the one against former vice-president
Moudud Ahmed, also wrongfully detained.
From jail, Ershad
won five constituencies he contested, and is still Chairman of Jaitya Party,
and a Member of Parliament. He was made special envoy to the prime minister in
the previous parliament.
That doesn’t
sound like an unpopular military ruler. Indeed, he seems to have been hard done
by, being detained wrongfully for years.
Again, we have
seen that more than 80% of hartals since 1947 have occurred after 1990, under
democratic rule. Hartals require enormous personnel, that is, a large body of
student thugs. People have been burnt alive in these hartals by both the toxic
leaders. Moreover, extrajudicial killings began under a democratically elected
government, and the military was used during Operation Clean
Heart in a manner unprecedented in the history of the
country. The death squad, the Rapid Action
Battalion, was formed in 2004 by the elected prime minister
Khaleda Zia and has been retained by her rival, Sheikh Hasina, no doubt for its
popularity in an increasingly violent and crime-ridden country.
Another aspect of
the situation that seems to have escaped the attention of Ms. Anam and Ayesha
Jalal is the corrosive effect of democracy on the judiciary, the last bastion
of the individual against despotic government.
According to Jean
Lipmen-Blumen, one characteristic destructive behaviour of toxic leaders
includes “Subverting those structures and processes of the system intended to
generate truth, justice and excellence and engaging in unethical, illegal and
criminal acts (The Allure of Toxic Leaders: Why We Follow Destructive Bosses
and Corrupt Politicians – and How We Can Resist Them (Oxford: Oxford University
Press) p 20).” Clearly, interfering with the judiciary constitutes such
behavior.
We have already
seen how the line between the judiciary and the executive was erased by the
Chief Justice himself when he became president in 1990.
In a conversation
in the early 1990s, B B Roy Chowdhury, then a judge on the Appellate Division
of the Supreme Court, told me, “He [General Ershad] never interfered with the
judiciary.” Ershad routinely used to lose case after case, but never tried to
influence the judges.
On the contrary, Ershad tried
repeatedly to make the lower judiciary independent of the executive - a move
not exactly associated with despotism. And repeatedly, he was thwarted by the
bureaucracy which had a vested interest in keeping the lower judiciary part of
the executive (again, B. B. Row Chowdhury detailed these events in
conversations with me). Finally, his dream was realised by the military
government of General Moeen U. Ahmed in 2007-8 after a coup.
Packing the
courts became routine under the elected governments. “There is a history of
politically stigmatized appointments to the highest judiciary as well as
ignoring the recommendations of the Chief Justice, either partially or wholly
by the government of the day,” proclaimed an editorial in the Daily Star
(August 25, 2006).
In 2007, Chief
Justice M. Ruhul Amin claimed that it would take twenty years to deliver the
judiciary from the effects of appointing judges on the basis of “political
considerations” (The Bangladesh Observer, May 1, 2007).
But the undoing
of the judiciary occurred in 1996. Sheikh Mujib, we will recall, was killed by
army officers. A grateful nation heaped honours on the assassins, and conferred
immunity against future persecution. This immunity was lifted in 1996 when
Mujib’s daughter, Sheikh Hasina, became prime minister. The lower judiciary sentenced
the men to death
by firing squad – there is no
provision for execution by firing squad in the laws – hoping no doubt to
ingratiate itself to the prime minister.
The higher
judiciary proved less pliable.
High Court judges
and then the Supreme Court refused
to hear the lower court's verdict: they declared themselves
'embarrassed' without explaining why. A
writer loyal to the dynasty observed: “It was amazing to see how
the virus of ‘embarrassment’ spread within the echelons of the judicial
hierarchy (Dhaka Tribune, August 15, 2016) .” On January 28, 2010, five of the
convicts were hanged – after Sheikh Hasina came to power again. How the
judiciary was finally brought around to hear the case must remain a matter of
conjecture and controversy.
Leaning on the
judiciary reached new heights when, for the first time in the country’s
history, the Chief Justice of the Supreme Court resigned. Surendra Kumar Sinha
says in his tell-all book published in exile in America, A
Broken Dream: Rule of Law, Democracy and Human Rights, that
he was forced to resign.
The nub of the
issue was the 16th amendment to the constitution which empowered
parliament to impeach judges of the Supreme Court. Along with his peers, he
upheld the High Court judgment that the amendment was illegal. “The Prime
Minister and other members of her party and ministers blasted me for going
against the Parliament,” he observes (p2). “Finally,” he concludes, “in the
face of intimidation and threats to my family and friends by the country’s
military intelligence agency called the Directorate General of the Defense
Forces Intelligence (DGDFI), I submitted [my] resignation from abroad.”
According to Al
Jazeera, Justice Sinha writes that he feared DGDFI might not
only "kill" a businessman named Aniruddha Roy, someone he knew well,
but also "members of my family". Unsurprisingly, the episode received
scant attention from the media in Bangladesh. The book was published in an
election year, but, as we have seen, most people polled were happy with the
direction the country was taking. The elite, for reasons unknown, declined to
enlighten the masses (who would have been totally at sea regarding the
separation of judiciary and executive in any case, such is the level of
political awareness at the grass-roots level.)
Recall how,
according to Jean Lupmen-Blumen, a characteristic behaviour of toxic leaders is
“Subverting those structures and processes of the system intended to generate
truth, justice and excellence and engaging in unethical, illegal and criminal
acts”. We have also seen examples of the suppression of peaceful protests by
student thugs of the ruling party. Now we come to the subject of strangling
criticism of the government.
In 2017, at
least twenty-five journalists and hundreds of bloggers and Facebook users were
prosecuted under the draconian Information and Communication Technology Act
(ICT) after their online content was deemed defamatory or blasphemous.
A sensation among
international civil society occurred upon the arrest of world-renowned
photo-journalist, Shahidul Alam, on August 5, 2018, after he spoke to Al
Jazeera and did a Facebook Live broadcast amid massive anti-government student
protests that gripped the country. He spent 107 days in jail until granted bail
by the High Court. He faced 14 years of imprisonment. In an
exclusive interview with Reuters, Sheikh Hasina, the prime minister,
described Alam as “mentally sick” and blamed his behavior on his family
background – Alam’s great uncle was on the opposing side to Hasina’s father,
Sheikh Mujib, in Bangladesh’s war of independence from Pakistan. (This is too
eerily redolent of Soviet
practice of labelling rebels as mad.)
Speaking about
Alam’s deceased great uncle, Abdus Sabur Khan, she observed, “He opposed our liberation
war, he joined Pakistan, he didn’t accept Bangladesh. In 1971 he was with the
Pakistani occupation army. Sometimes blood speaks, you understand that.” It
appears that vice as well as virtue are heritable.
In one of a dozen
Facebook videos he posted from the protest site, Alam said he had been attacked
and had his camera smashed by “goons” wielding metal rods and sticks from the Chatra
League, the student thugs of the ruling party.
“The police
specifically asked for help from these armed goons to combat unarmed students
demanding safe roads,” alleged Alam on Al Jazeera, as reported by
Channel 4. “I mean, how ridiculous is that?”
His detention was
a clear signal to any would-be whistleblowers or dissenters of the fate that
would await them.
In contrast, I
remember going down to a theatre in the ‘80s to watch a play performed by a
troupe of local actors in Bangladesh. The play was called The
Captain of Kopenick.
The play was
about a down-on-his-luck ex-convict shoemaker. He is ignored by everyone until
he dons a military uniform – and achieves instant respectability.
The play,
performed in Bengali, was a flagrant caricature of the rule of General Ershad,
who had acquired power through a military coup in 1982.
However, the play
was not banned, the actors were never arrested or even prosecuted. I went home
that evening, much amused.
The Economist observed: “Despite considerable turbulence since breaking from Pakistan following a bloody war in 1971, Bangladesh has a tradition of respect for dissent. This has eroded in recent years as the Awami League, which itself had been a victim of previous purges, has turned on its rivals with a vengeance.” Thus, state repression was never as severe as it has become: the military did not, in all fairness, crush dissent. The democrats have.
But the media of
Bangladesh will tell readers and viewers of how we moved from dictatorship to
democracy on December 6, 1990, when Ershad resigned, a day commemorated every
year as ‘democracy day’.
We have seen the
psychology of the elite in Bangladesh, their rational as well as extra-rational
motives for an anti-empirical faith in democracy and toxic leaders. I quote at
length from Bertrand Russell’s essay On Being Modern-Minded a passage brimful
of sentiments that can’t quite be conveyed by a social or political
psychologist. His observations combine the blending of the irrational need to
belong to a heard, the fear of social death, not being one of the chosen, to
the rational need for career, kudos and cash:
“A mentally
solitary life, such as that of Copernicus, or Spinoza, or Milton after the
Restoration, seems pointless according to modern standards....And in any case
what is the use of an eccentric opinion, which never can hope to conquer the
great agencies of publicity? The money rewards and widespread though ephemeral
fame which those agencies have made possible place temptations in the way of
able men which are difficult to resist. To be pointed out, admired, mentioned
constantly in the press, and offered easy ways of earning much money is highly
agreeable; and when all this is open to a man, he finds it difficult to go on
doing the work that he himself thinks best and is inclined to subordinate his judgment
to the general opinion (Unpopular Essays (Bombay: Blackie & Son (India)
Ltd, 1979), pp. 66-67).”
We have traced
the killers of Mahima to the voters, the people, and the elite, obedient to two
pathological leaders, who are ultimately the guilty.
But does the buck
stop there?
Democracy did not
descend from heaven, but from the western donors. It was they who created the situation,
the ‘bad barrel of Bangladesh’, they were the system makers who have
perpetuated a situation where formerly decent people became evil.
The reader will
recall Milgram’s 35%, the subjects who refused to shock the victim despite
repeated exhortations from authority. She will also recall Christina Maslach, the ‘heroine’ of the
Stanford Prison Experiment, who persuaded Zimbardo to terminate his experiment
with the twenty-four young men, all previously screened for any abnormality in
their personality.
In
2004, two concerned citizens of Bangladesh wished to put an end to the toxic
rule of the two dynasties – with ‘permission’ from America! If it hadn’t been
for Julian Assange and WikiLeaks, we would never have known how the superpower
sealed our doom. Former army chief and Awami League minister Lt General (retd)
Noorudin Khan supplicated support from the US government to end Bangladesh's
administration in 2004 and bring a government of national unity consisting of
senior leaders from both the major parties. Also, another ex-chief of
Bangladesh Army and standing committee member of BNP, Lt Gen (retd) Mahbubur
Rahman, had told the US ambassador that the military would always look to the
US government for a signal to go ahead with a coup. Ambassador Harry K Thomas
refused, saying the US would uphold stability and democracy and would not
countenance any extra-constitutional measures (The Daily Star, September 7,
2011).
The
two military officers had been prescient, and on January 11, 2007, the
military, under the guise of a civilian administration, took over power: the
country was on the verge of collapse. An election was scheduled to take place
on January 22, which the BNP planned to rig. “Delaying the vote averted a
possible bloodbath,” opined The Economist.
The
political cycle of Bangladesh seems to go something like this:
civilian
rule – extreme situation – military rule – civilian rule – extreme situation –
military rule…
The
force that saves a country in extreme situations constitutes the sovereign,
according to Carl Schmitt (after Thomas Hobbes). We have never developed a
notion of the modern state, as noted above, due to romantic attachments to
language or spiritual cravings for religion. Thus, our last bulwark against
anarchy and chaos is the military.
The
military government of General Moeen U Ahmed proved highly popular (except
among the extra-rational loyalists of the two begums, especially when both were
incarcerated by the army). In a letter to the Bangladesh Observer, a citizen of
the country, Nur Jahan, expressed her gratitude to the military-backed caretaker
government: “When everything was falling apart, we were feeling like [we were]
on board a ship in a stormy sea, which might sink any moment. At that critical
time the caretaker government held the helm firmly and steered us safely to the
shore (April 17, 2008)”. Even novelist Tahmima Anan had good things to say
about the military takeover, as we saw above. This is small wonder, when
General Moeen U Ahmed appeared in TIME magazine with a handsome profile. America had clearly
changed its mind.
But
like mythological tales of ancient Greece, the ending proved less than
euphoric, for the two toxic leaders were soon back in politics; Khaleza Zia
carried out deadly hartals, and Sheikh Hasina has continued as premier until
today, her rival locked up on corruption charges. Democracy is back with all
its pathologies.
The
journalist Gwynne Dyer, writing in The Telegraph, informs us that General Moeen’s view
was that “essentially democracy is to blame”. He dismisses this out of hand. “And
the general doesn’t think democracy is right for Bangladesh. But if it isn’t
right for Bengalis, one of the most politicized, argumentative populations on
the planet, then just who is it right for?” He ends his article with the old
chestnut from Churchill: “Democracy is the worst form of government — except
all the others that have been tried from time to time.”
Western
donors are the barrel-makers: but why this insistence on a system of government
that has taken so many lives in Bangladesh, often in the most gruesome form,
and ruined the lives of countless young people, including teenagers?
For
the murder of Mahima must, in the last analysis, be attributed to the West. Guilty.
But what was the motive?
A New Religion
I
was an English language teacher at a Catholic seminary in Dhaka on Asad Avenue
called the Oblates of Mary Immaculate (OMI). After class, I used to have
regular conversations with the rector, Fr. Bejoy D’ Cruz, a short, portly young
man with intent eyes.
One
afternoon, over a cup of coffee, he was telling me how difficult it had become
to recruit young men to the priesthood. He said that young people in the west
preferred to join NGOs.
This
was a revelation.
We
have seen that people in Bangladesh join or set up NGOs for rational reasons –
money. However, westerners do the same for the old, extra-rational motives that
once directed them to the pews and pulpits. The number of priests and nuns have been declining in the occident, the
number of nuns especially so, the total of those not called offset by the
increasing ranks from Asia and Africa. All over Europe and North America
(albeit, as mentioned, not in Asia and Africa), the numbers of priests and
parishioners will continue their remorseless decline, as observed by a newspaper. I started class with eight seminarians,
and next year there were sixteen. God has emigrated.
In
a conversation with an American priest, Br. Donald, he said it was much better
to be here in Bangladesh, where people take religion seriously, than in
America.
Charles
Taylor, in A Secular Age, discusses the issue of ‘meaning’ as addressed by a
French thinker, Luc Ferry (p 677). The latter gives instances of young people
who have achieved a strong sense of meaning in their lives through membership
of Medecins Sans Frontieres, but ‘horizontally’, not ‘vertically’. No doubt,
similar observations can be made about membership of other NGOs, like Amnesty
International or Article 19. Thus, people find meaning in their lives through
something greater than themselves, without being other-worldly. But they,
nevertheless, manifest a need for transcendence.
Again,
the same writer observes the mobilisation of resources in the event of a
distant calamity, such as a flood or earthquake. He attributes this outpouring
of empathy not only to the media and methods of transportation and the fact of
economic plenitude, but something less tangible, not unconnected to the
Christian past. “The same media and means of transport don’t awaken the same
response everywhere; it is disproportionately strong in ex-Latin Christendom (p
371).”
Taylor
observes that new forms arise in history in spiritual traditions which are
carried forward and reshaped so that subsequent periods show the same spiritual
inclinations in a revised, but mirrored form. “I have argued that this is true
for exclusive humanism in relation to Christian faith, in the centrality of
benevolence, for instance. I have even argued that exclusive humanism couldn’t
have arisen without this analogue to agape. (pp 679-680)” Indeed, religion is
reconstituted.
A
similar line of thought emerges in Democracy in Europe, by Larry Siedentop (Harmondsworth:
Allen Lane The Penguin Press, 2000). More interesting than Taylor, Siedentop
traces democracy to Christianity. He observes: “For the Christian God survives
in the assumption that we have access to the nature of things as individuals. That assumption is, in
turn, the final justification for a democratic society, for a society organised
to respect the equal underlying moral status of all its members, by
guaranteeing each ‘equal liberty’. That assumption reveals how the notion of
‘Christian liberty’ came to underpin a radically new ‘democratic’ model of
human association (p 194, italics original)”.
“Mediaeval
noblemen did not believe in individualism”, observes Harari in Sapiens (p 128).
One’s place in the social hierarchy determined one’s worth. Teenage sons of
barons did not have private rooms on the second floor of the castle “with
posters of Richard the Lionheart and King Arthur on the walls”, let alone a
locked door closed to parental supervision. He slept with other boys in a large
hall, always on display and always alert to what others saw and said. It was
the hierarchy and others’ perception of him that determined his true worth.
The
individual makes his first appearance through Machiavelli and Luther, according
to Alasdair McIntyre (A Short History of Ethics, London: Routledge and Kegan
Paul, 1967, p 121). “For the first time, the Absolute Individual confronts the
Absolute State” wrote J.N.Figgis, as quoted by McIntyre, of the period after
the Reformation (p 124).
Siedentop
bemoans the lack of shared beliefs in Europe and the lack of democracy (hence
the title, deliberately echoing Tocqueville’s book). The latter is due to the
former, for which he blames anti-clericalism and multiculturalism (sometimes
together).
Anti-clericalism
hardly consists with this benign view of Christianity. Christianity has been
consistent with persecution, autos-da-fe, slavery, serfdom, absolutism, war, racism,
capitalism, and, today, democracy (as he claims). Siedentop takes
anti-clericalism as an unfortunate aspect of European culture today without
querying its origins, motivation and legitimacy. In recent times, clerical sexual abuse of children as well
as nuns, along with the
concomitant cover-ups, have confirmed the worst suspicions of the
anti-clerical.
“Thus,
the defining characteristic of Christianity was its universalism. It aimed to
create a single human society, a society composed, that is, of individuals
rather than tribes, clans or castes.” It is Christian ontology that undergirds
liberal values. The primary and foundational commitments to equality,
reciprocity and individual freedom are constitutive of Western society; the
commitments to tolerance, pluralism and scepticism are derivative and secondary
(p 210).
Siedentop
claims that Christianity, unlike other faiths, “interiorizes God”. Christianity
is not a social group worshipping itself a la Durkheim, but a social group
premised on the individual as a free agent. This interiorization is the source
of conscience and a sphere of choice protected by human rights. “That is the
kernel of truth embedded in the Protestant version of Christianity – the kernel
which makes it plausible to claim that Protestantism, for all its aberrations,
is a more self-conscious form of Christianity than Catholicism (p 211).”
Islam,
and multiculturalism, come in for heavy criticism. Clearly, Islam is deficient
and defective, and its values “abhorrent”. Islam prioritises men over women,
fathers over daughters, husbands over wives (curiously Siedentop doesn’t expend
much energy on Hinduism which as we have seen, is characterised by the Homo
hierarchicus; the sex ratio at birth in Bangladesh, a Muslim country, is 1.04 males per female, while in India it is 1.12 males per female, a result of female foeticide unknown in
Bangladesh. When Nehru passed away, his daughter, Indira, was not able to light
the funeral pyre; that duty fell to Indira’s son, Sanjay. Son-preference runs
deep in India (Nehru: A Political Biography (p 7)).
Mahima
was a simple Muslim girl – young, but nevertheless deficient for being Muslim.
A Christian, European girl would not have killed herself because her society
would regard her as a person first, a woman, a daughter, a wife, second.
Failing the family honour (a collective sentiment) would have been intolerable,
a social death. She chose an actual death.
Siedentop
approves of the “superb” spread of the language of human rights throughout the
world, constituting an almost universal culture, the “ultimate and least
resistible form of Western influence, something which must appear to defenders
of other faiths as the last form of Western imperialism (p 213)”.
We
have seen throughout this essay that the pursuit of democracy and the pursuit
of human rights have been at odds in Bangladesh, and indeed, in South Asia.
Assault and battery of children protesters, extrajudicial killings and
disappearances, far from denting the popularity of an elected government, in
fact augments it. Nor is the issue of human rights free of incoherence: the
right of the foetus versus the right of a woman to abortion are vehemently disputed
issues even in the West. The rights of workers to job security vary between
continental capitalism and Anglo-Saxon capitalism, and so on. Torture seems to
be employed even by liberal regimes whenever national security is threatened. An
Irish plebiscite legalised gay marriage in 2015: does
that mean that the majority can confer a right, or take it away?
As
one would expect from someone who believes in universal values, Siedentop
maintains that “the only form of Western imperialism that remains legitimate is
ideological (p 188)”.
Interestingly,
no other civilisation seems to wish to project its values onto the world, no
doubt because these values are parochial and particularistic. The reader will
have noticed that criticism of democracy in these pages have come from
anthropologists, who are necessarily interested in the parochial and particular
(and one politician philosopher, similarly focussed on the empirical and real).
The
time has come to raise the all-important question (‘the million-dollar
question’ if not so many lives had been involved): Despite all the evidence, from
political psychologists, social psychologists, journalists, historians,
anthropologists…despite all the evidence, why does this faith in democracy
endure – in the west? (In Bangladesh, we have looked at both rational and
irrational reasons for such faith).
Happily,
the European elite have fewer illusions about democracy. Jean Monnet has been quoted
by The Economist as having “thought it wrong to consult
the peoples of Europe about the structure of a community of which they had no
practical experience”. However, the European Union vigorously champions
democracy in Bangladesh, even going to the extent of whitewashing fake
elections (with the Carter Centre, as we saw above). And even as Jeanne
Kirkpatrick was writing her classic essay on dictatorship and double standards,
she observed that “No idea holds greater sway in the mind of educated
Americans than the belief that it is possible to democratise governments,
anytime and anywhere, under any circumstances.”
The
invaluable question was posed in the 1930s by Joseph Schumpeter in his book Capitalism,
Socialism and Democracy (New York: Harper and Row, 1950): “But how is it
possible that a doctrine so patently contrary to fact should have survived to
this day and continued to hold its place in the hearts of the people and in the
official language of governments? The refuting facts are known to all;
everybody admits them with perfect, frequently with cynical, frankness. The
theoretical basis, utilitarian rationalism, is dead; nobody accepts it as a
correct theory of the body politic. Nevertheless, that question is not
difficult to answer (pp 264 – 265).”
Before
answering the question, Schumpeter presents arguments against the
eighteenth-century view of democracy, which he defines as “the democratic
method is that institutional arrangement for arriving at political decisions
which realizes the common good by making the people itself decide issues
through the election of individuals who are to assemble in order to carry out
its will (p 250)”. Then he draws the implications of the definition.
He
affirms that there is no common good which everyone can be persuaded to accept
by rational considerations. On the level of the individual will, we, in a
democracy, will have to attribute to it a level of independence and rationality
that are “altogether unrealistic”, meaning, anti-empirical.
“Everyone
would have to know definitely what he wants to stand for. This definite will
would have to be implemented by the ability to observe and interpret correctly
the facts that are directly accessible to everyone and to sift critically the
information about the facts that are not. Finally, from that definite will and
from these ascertained facts a clear and prompt conclusion as to particular issues
would have to be derived according to the rules of logical inference—with so
high a degree of general efficiency moreover that one man’s opinion could be
held, without glaring absurdity, to be roughly as good as every other man’s (pp
253 – 254).” And all this the citizen would have to accomplish by herself,
‘unaided’ by pressure groups or propaganda.
Under
the rubric “Human Nature in Politics”, Schumpeter begins thus: “It remains to
answer our question about the definiteness and independence of the voter’s
will, his powers of observation and interpretation of facts, and his ability to
draw, clearly and promptly, rational inferences from both. This subject belongs
to a chapter of social psychology that might be entitled Human Nature in
Politics (p 256).”
The
reader will recall the title of the book by Graham Wallas mentioned before
under the heading ‘The Irrational’. Schumpeter recommends the book as “the best
introduction to political psychology”. (He takes Wallas to task for not taking
his own premises to their logical conclusion!)
He
gives a brief history of the demolition of the ‘rational’ individual. “During
the second half of the last century, the idea of the human personality that is
a homogeneous unit and the idea of a definite will that is the prime mover of
action have been steadily fading—even before the times of Théodule Ribot and of
Sigmund Freud. In particular, these ideas have been increasingly discounted in
the field of social sciences where the importance of the extra-rational and irrational
element in our behavior has been receiving more and more attention, witness
Pareto’s Mind and Society. Of the many sources of the evidence that accumulated
against the hypothesis of rationality, I shall mention only two.”
The
first he mentions is the name of Gustav Le Bon, the pioneer in the study of the
psychology of crowds (psychologie des foules). Schumpeter extends the denotation of
‘crowd’ to include “every parliament, every committee, every council of war”
for they share with the rabble “a reduced sense of responsibility, a lower
level of energy of thought and greater sensitiveness to non-logical
influences”.
“Moreover,
those phenomena are not confined to a crowd in the sense of a physical
agglomeration of many people. Newspaper readers, radio audiences, members of a
party even if not physically gathered together are terribly easy to work up
into a psychological crowd and into a state of frenzy in which attempt at
rational argument only spurs the animal spirits (p 257).”
The
second source he mentions is, in some ways, more illuminating. “Economists,
learning to observe their facts more closely, have begun to discover that, even
in the most ordinary currents of daily life, their consumers do not quite live
up to the idea that the economic textbook used to convey.” He has, in fact,
anticipated the discipline known today as Behavioural Economics. As we have
seen, Richard H. Thaler draws a distinction between Econs and Humans, the
former being the fictional creature of economic theory and the latter the
flesh-and-blood people of everyday life. Just as the rational individual is a
textbook fiction, so the rational citizen is an ideological construct.
In
the next section, Schumpeter asks his invaluable question. His answer is
equally invaluable.
“First
of all, though the classical doctrine of collective action may not be
supported-by the results of empirical analysis, it is powerfully supported by
that association with religious belief to which I have adverted already. This
may not be obvious at first sight. The utilitarian leaders were anything but
religious in the ordinary sense of the term. In fact they believed themselves
to be anti-religious and they were so considered almost universally. They took
pride in what they thought was precisely an unmetaphysical attitude and they
were quite out of sympathy with the religious institutions and the religious
movements of their time. But we need only cast another glance at the picture
they drew of the social process in order to discover that it embodied essential
features of the faith of protestant Christianity and was in fact derived from
that faith. For the intellectual who had cast off his religion the utilitarian
creed provided a substitute for it. For many of those who had retained their
religious belief the classical doctrine became the political complement of it
(p 265).”
This
explains why democracy is beyond criticism and rational evaluation: the
dissident is not only wrong, but morally wrong, a heretic, as was the case with
Marxism.
“It
actually becomes what from another standpoint I have held it incapable of
becoming, viz., an ideal or rather a part of an ideal schema of things. The
very word may become a flag, a symbol of all a man holds dear, of everything
that he loves about his nation whether rationally contingent to it or not. On
the one hand, the question how the various propositions implied in the
democratic belief are related to the facts of politics will then become as
irrelevant to him as is, to the believing Catholic, the question how the doings
of Alexander VI tally with the supernatural halo surrounding the papal office.
On the other hand, the democrat of this type, while accepting postulates
carrying large implications about equality and brotherliness, will be in a
position also to accept, in all sincerity, almost any amount of deviations from
them that his own behavior or position may involve. That is not even illogical.
Mere distance from fact is no argument against an ethical maxim or a mystical
hope (p 266).”
Aldous
Huxley made similar observations about democracy, the religion. “The word
[democracy] conjures up ideas of universal liberty and happiness. The hearer
feels an expansive emotion, a pleasing enlargement of his personality,
following on the idea of the loosening of restraints. He can be moved by
repetition of the word to take violent action (A Few Well-chosen Words, Aldous
Huxley: Complete Essays, Volume II, 1926-1929, ed. Robert S. Baker and James
Sexton, (Chicago: Ivan R. Dee, 2000), pp 59 - 60).”
These
words were prescient. Violent action has indeed been taken to spread the faith
across the Middle East. However, when a Palestinian uses the word ‘democracy’,
he means oppression. When a Rohingya refugee fleeing from newly-democratic
Burma hears the world, it is safe to assume that no pleasant associations come
to his or her mind.
Huxley
continues: “As a matter of historical fact, however, democracy has come to
mean, not universal liberty, but the absolute rule of majorities. In republican
America the formula of democracy is: Agree with the majority, or clear out.” He
writes like a contemporary observer of American politics.
Huxley,
too, was aware of the sacred nature of democracy. He writes: “Only the most
mystically fervent democrats, who regard voting as a kind of religious act, and
who hear the voice of God in that of the People, can have any reason to desire
to perpetuate a system whereby confidence tricksters, rich men, and quacks may
be given power by the votes of an electorate composed in a great part of mental
Peter Pans, whose childishness renders them peculiarly susceptible to the
blandishments of demagogues and the tirelessly repeated suggestions of the rich
men’s newspapers (Political Democracy, p 228).” (When I quoted these words to
an English friend of mine, he said, “Was he on mescaline?”. Huxley was writing four years before Hitler’s electoral success.)
We
have seen that political and social psychologists have confirmed his view about
“mental Peter Pans”, and as for the rich men, Bernie Sanders thundered “We allowed rich people to buy
the US government”. He said that he didn’t have a super PAC, through which the
rich channel their donations. By August 2015, he had raised $15.2 million
dollars from 350,000 supporters, who, on average, contributed $31. Last year, Jeremy Corbyn referred to the “stranglehold of elite
power and billionaire domination over large parts of our media”.
Schumpeter
and Huxley noted the anti-empiricism mentioned above, infecting not only the
layman but also the historian (such as Ayesha Jalal). Like Siedentop,
Schumpeter traces democratic values back to Christianity, but without the
former’s glorification. “Thus transposed into the categories of religion, this
doctrine—and in consequence the kind of democratic persuasion which is based
upon it— changes its very nature. There is no longer any need for logical
scruples about the Common Good and Ultimate Values. All this is settled for us
by the plan of the Creator whose purpose defines and sanctions everything. What
seemed indefinite or unmotivated before is suddenly quite definite and
convincing. The voice of the people that is the voice of God for instance. Or
take Equality. Its very meaning is in doubt, and there is hardly any rational
warrant for exalting it into a postulate, so long as we move in the sphere of
empirical analysis. But Christianity harbors a strong equalitarian element. The
Redeemer died for all: He did not differentiate between individuals of
different social status. In doing so, He testified to the intrinsic value of
the individual soul, a value that admits of no gradations. Is not this a
sanction—and, as it seems to me, the only possible sanction —of “everyone to
count for one, no one to count for more than one”—a sanction that pours
super-mundane meaning into articles of the democratic creed for which it is not
easy to find any other (p 265)?”
The
goodness of democracy is thereby ‘evidence-transcendent’, for it is God’s plan
for humanity. We have seen how Charles Taylor conceived of the reconstitution
of religion in the secular. Nineteenth century Europe was a time of secular
religions: nationalism, Marxism and democracy each arrived as new religions for
a new society. (Even among Arabs, faith
in the fundamental goodness of democracy was in full display in 2011,
notwithstanding the clear and contradictory evidence of Iraq.)
A
‘secular religion’, far from being an oxymoron, is an identifiable social
phenomenon. According to Ninian Smart, in his book The World’s Religions (Englewood
Cliffs, N.J.: Prentice Hall, 1989, pp 10 - 25), every religion has seven
characteristics, or dimensions. We tick them off one by one, with respect to
nationalism:
(1)
the ritual dimension: speaking the language, saluting the flag, national
holidays, pilgrimages to sights
considered important; (2) the experiential or emotional dimension: nationalism
has a powerful emotional side, a fact that seems to me to explain why children
are peculiarly susceptible to it, as during the Chinese May 4th Movement, or
the 21st February 1952 students’ movement in the then-East Pakistan (today
Bangladesh); these emotions are always kept simmering below the surface through
patriotic or heroic songs, dramas…(3) the narrative dimension is obvious in
nationalism: the history of the nation; the stories (fictionalized, or
embellished) of great men, women and even children who made the nation what it
is; (4) unlike the emotional dimension, nationalism lacks a strong doctrinal
dimension, reinforcing my observation that the power of the emotional aspect
renders nationalist sentiments peculiarly appealing to children; however,
nationalism can appeal to a set of doctrines, such as democracy, individual
freedom and rights (or it could appeal to purely religious doctrines as well);
(5) the ethical dimension of nationalism refers to loyalty to the nation,
martial values needed during defense (or offence), family values (to provide
soldiers); (6) the social and institutional aspect of the nation-state consists
in such public figures as the head of state, the army and its military
ceremonies, the education system – a formidable apparatus for collective
indoctrination – and even in games (the Olympics is the egregious example); (7)
finally, the material dimension of religion are the physical monuments and
artistic objects that have been created by the ‘nation-builders’.
Smart
then goes on to adumbrate the seven dimensions of Marxism.
It
should be clear to the reader that democracy, like nationalism and Marxism, has
similar characteristics:
(1)
First, there’s the ritual dimension of the quinquennial vote, the municipal and
local elections, the swearing-in ceremonies....At election time, the people
come together. Voters vote for the national good (however ill-equipped they are
to determine this) and not just for their narrow self-interest (Against
Democracy, p 49). There is a period of transcendence at election time, lasting
several weeks, if not months. (2) Then there’s the experiential or emotional
aspect: every election is preceded by months of campaigning during which
euphoria and heightened expectations prevail. (3) The narrative or mythical
dimension of democracy is fairly obvious: there’s the identification over 2,500
years with Cleisthenes and Greek democracy, the Glorious Revolution, the
American Revolution….Locally, there is the identification with those who
overthrew a 'tyrant': in Bangladesh, December 6, 1990 is recalled every year as
the day General Ershad was overthrown by brave boys (who were in reality thugs,
but never mind); in America, the 4th of July serves a similar purpose. (4)
Democracy, more than nationalism, has a far richer doctrinal dimension, ranging
from - to take an arbitrary span - the treatises of John Locke to the output of
John Stuart Mill. (5) The ethical dimension: values (observed in the breach) of
tolerance, equality, accountability, are inculcated in voters. (6) The social
and institutional aspects of democracy stand out – literally: there’s the elected
President or Prime Minister with his or her regalia and elaborate ceremonies; the
‘people’ are represented through popular songs, dances, dramas, poetry and
folk-tales. (7) The material embodiment of democracy is often magnificent: in
Bangladesh there’s the Assembly Building designed by Louis Kahn; The Capitol,
the White House and Westminster Palace are imposing monuments to democracy. As
de Tocqueville observed: “Nowhere do citizens appear so insignificant as in a
democratic nation; nowhere does the nation itself appear greater, or does the
mind more easily take in a wide general survey of it. In democratic communities
the imagination is compressed when men consider themselves; it expands
indefinitely when they think of the State. Hence it is that the same men who
live on a small scale in narrow dwellings, frequently aspire to gigantic
splendor in the erection of their public monuments (Alexis de Tocqueville, Democracy in America, trans. Henry Reeve, Book 2, Chapter 12).”
Not surprisingly, even democratic architecture conduces to a feeling of
transcendence.
The
highest level of human growth, according to Abraham Maslow, is that of
transcendence. Transcendence, for Maslow, encompasses the need to rise above
the interests of the self, to find fulfilment in helping others reach their
potential (The Allure of Toxic Leaders, p 129).
According
to Jean Lipman-Blumen, control myths are rationalisations that we use to
persuade ourselves to act or desist from acting, and these are deep-buried in
our subconscious existential, psychological and psychosocial needs. “Both
because of and despite the fact that they travel incognito, these powerful
control myths prevent us from even attempting to overthrow toxic leaders (p
130).” She lists several control myths, but the most powerful and positive ones
come at the end, or at the top, for they promise ennoblement and immortality,
thus speaking to the needs that Maslow describes as self-esteem,
self-actualisation and transcendence. A few samples follow (pp 135-136).
“This
leader is an unique being. Participating in his/her vision will make me unique,
too.” (Self-esteem and belonging; self-actualisation and transcendence.)
“Whatever
promises the leader makes will come true.” (Safety)
“This
leader’s vision is so ennobling, I would follow her to the ends of the earth.”
(Self-actualisation and transcendence)
“When
I am part of the leader’s group, I can do no wrong.” (Aesthetic [order,
symmetry and beauty]; self-actualisation and transcendence)
“Being
part of the leader’s group fills me with a sense of doing something really
important.” (Cognition and transcendence)
“The
vision is worth any sacrifice.” (Transcendence)
“Attaining
the vision through my heroic efforts will earn me immortality.” (Transcendence)
The
writer adds: “Believing in the special, god-like qualities of the leader makes
it difficult to evaluate his claims to mana.”
“They
beat her to death with their clubs,” wrote a student about his teacher. “It was immensely satisfying.”
This
was a clear example of thumos run amok, and used by a toxic leader to further
his personal agenda.
“The
Great Proletarian Cultural Revolutionary bugle to advance” first sounded 52
years ago, on May 16th 1966, when Mao approved a secret circular declaring war
on “representatives of the bourgeoisie” who had “sneaked into the Communist
Party, the government, the army and various spheres of culture”. Between May
1966 and Mao’s death in 1976, which in effect ended the Cultural Revolution,
over 1 million died, millions more were banished from urban homes to the countryside
and tens of millions were humiliated or tortured.
How
could an entire nation follow a toxic leader like Mao Zedong? Jean Marie-Lupmen
has a few answers. She also explains the allure of toxic leaders in Bangladesh,
Pakistan, India and other places like Cambodia and the Soviet Union.
Mao
stood on the threshold of Paradise, Communism, the end of prehistory and the
beginning of history. A few million deaths seemed a paltry sacrifice in a
cost-benefit analysis. He stood at the terminus of human civilisation, the Prophet
over the Promised Land, with his eager Communist disciples.
Charles
Taylor, although the winner of the Templeton Prize, is clear-eyed about the
history of Christianity, unlike Siedentop, and the dangers to the devout. He
observes:
“So
religious faith can be dangerous. Opening to transcendence is fraught with
peril. But this is particularly so if we respond to these perils by permanent
closure, drawing an unambiguous boundary between the pure and the impure
through the polarization of conflict, even war. That religious believers are
capable of this, history amply attests. But atheists can as well, once they
open themselves to strong ideals, such as a republic of equals, a world order
of perpetual peace, or communism. We find the same self-assurance of purity
through aggressive attack on “axes of evil”, among believers and atheists alike.
Idolatry breeds violence (p 769).”
Bertrand
Russell once wrote: “Belief in democracy, however, like any other belief, may
be carried to the point where it becomes fanatical and therefore harmful (‘Ideas
That Have Harmed Mankind’, Unpopular Essays (Bombay: Blackie & Son (India)
Ltd, 1979), p. 149).”
But
belief in democracy is not like any
other belief, just as belief in the goodness of God and His plans for humanity is
not like any other belief. Belief in the goodness of democracy is evidence-transcendent: it exists
despite all evidence to the contrary. Brennan insists, time and again, that “democracy
is not a poem or painting (p 125)”, that it must be evaluated just as we would
evaluate a hammer, as a means to an end, not an end in itself (p 14). In this,
he harks backs to Schumpeter’s contention that we must be able to discuss
democracy “rationally like a steam engine or a disinfectant (p 266).”
And
we have seen that, in Bangladesh, belief in democracy, unlike any other belief
today, may be carried to the point where it becomes fanatical and therefore highly profitable. For a section of our
intelligentsia, belief in democracy is extremely rational.
Take
a contemporary and pressing instance of the disjunction between democratic
reality and democratic faith. It comes from Latin America, where the
Latinobarometro survey reported in the Economist shows great dissatisfaction with
democracy and a simultaneous preference for democracy!
The
proportion of people who are dissatisfied with how democracy works has jumped
from 51% in 2009 to 71%. The share that is content has dropped from 44% to 24%,
its lowest level since the survey began more than two decades ago. However, more
than half say that it is better than any other system, though that has dropped
by 13 percentage points over the past eight years. The share who are neutral
has risen from 16% in 2010 to 28%.
The
chasm between reality and aspiration is deepest in Venezuela, where more than
half the people say they do not have enough to eat. Although just 12% of
Venezuelans are happy with how their “democracy” functions, 75% prefer
democracy to any other system. Yet it was the democratically elected Hugo
Chavez and his successor Nicolas Maduro who helped to take the food out of
their mouths. Millions voted with their feet.
(On
the other hand, Nigerians have turned out to be more rational: in the 2015
presidential election, turnout was just 43%; in the last one, it dropped to 35.6%. Nigerians have learned from experience,
and they may also have been doing a little basis arithmetic: the value of a
vote is 1 divided by the number of voters – a value almost equalling zero,
which makes voting irrational (Against Democracy, p 110).)
A
variant of theodicy seems to be at work in appraising democracy. On the cusp of
religion and politics, I turn for assistance to a poet, Edmund Blunden, and his
heart-wrenching poem, Report on Experience.
I
have been young, and now am not too old;
And
I have seen the righteous forsaken,
His
health, his honour and his quality taken.
This is not what we were formerly told.
I
have seen a green county, useful to the race,
Knocked
silly with guns and mines, its villages vanished,
Even
the last rat and last kestrel banished―
God bless us all, this was peculiar grace.
I
knew Seraphina ; Nature gave her hue,
Glance,
sympathy, note, like one from Eden.
I
saw her smile warp, heard her lyric deaden;
She turned to harlotry;― this I took to be
new.
Say
what you will, our God sees how they run.
These
disillusions are his curious proving
That
he loves humanity and will go on loving;
Over there are faith, life, virtue in the
sun.
There
can be no quarrel with the last quatrain, just as there can be none with the
first three: this tension is part and parcel of religious faith. But when we
ask why sixteen-year-old Ripon Sikder had to be burned alive, taking eleven
days to die, it is not our faith in God, but our faith in democracy, that is,
or should be, shaken.
“’They
were only war casualties,” he said. “It was a pity, but you can’t always hit
your target. Anyway they died in the right cause.’
‘“Would
you have said the same if it had been your old nurse with her blueberry pie?”
“He
ignored my facile point. ‘In a way you could say, they died for democracy.’”
Readers
will recall this exchange between the English journalist Thomas Fowler, the
narrator, and the undercover OSS agent, Arden Pyle, in The Quiet American by Graham
Greene (Harmondsworth: Penguin, 1955, p 179).
In
the event, 4-5 million Vietnamese men, women and children died for democracy.
When one has God on one’s side, and the others don’t, it is legitimate to kill.
Fowler’s
facile point about “your old nurse with her blueberry pie” raises the essential
question: what if he/she were one of ‘us’, and not one of ‘them’?
Charles
Taylor similarly raises the essential question: “And sympathy can so easily be
blocked by ideology, even (though rarely) in the case of one’s own children,
but certainly when it comes to others (A Secular Age, p 701)”. With the
followers of Jim Jones, we have seen that sympathy can be blocked even in the
case of one’s own children.
In
Party Animals: My Family and Other
Communists, David
Aaronovitch details his parents’ love of the Soviet Union and Communism. Anything
could be justified to a true believer, even Stalinism. “Perhaps there are
children of very devout Muslims or evangelicals who will read this and nod
along,” he muses.
In
the late ‘80s when the Soviet Union was on the skids, the late Debesh Bhattacharya
told me, “We will become angels”. He had gone to prison for his Marxist faith
when Bangladesh was East Pakistan. He retired as a judge on the Supreme Court.
His wife, Chitra Bhattacharya, became MP for the ruling Awami League. Both
their sons had studied in Moscow.
Postscript
Is it possible that
every one of our military rulers had good dispositions, and that every one of
our democratically elected rulers had bad dispositions?
This seems farfetched.
Instead of appealing to dispositions, explanations along situationist lines
would be more illuminating.
First of all, there is
no political hatred when politics is in abeyance, almost by definition. Society
under military rule was not divided between us and them, ingroup and outgroup. Under
military rule, there is no political hatred, simply because there is no
politics.
Even in a peaceful
democracy like America – invariably held up as a model for the world, ‘the city
on the hill’ – democracy creates civic or situational enemies. Even before the
election of Donald Trump, more than half of Democrats told
pollsters that they were afraid of Republicans and almost
half of Republicans said the same about Democrats.
Cass Sunstein observes
that in 1960, only about 4 to 5 percent of Republicans and Democrats would be
‘displeased’ if their children married members of the opposite party; now,
about 43% of Republicans and 33% of Democrats admit they would be displeased
(Against Democracy, p 234).
Violence is never far
below the surface even in the oldest democracy. After a Republican congressman
was shot by an unstable gunman last summer, leading Democrats expressed outrage
at the idea that their rhetoric had played any part. Yet they used the
attempted bombings and the synagogue shooting to begin a debate about the
precise degree of presidential responsibility for domestic terrorism.
In the Mother of
Parliaments, tribalism has descended like an evil mantle. On June 16, 2016, Labour
MP Jo Cox was murdered by a troubled, far-right
52-year-old gardener. Working-class Labour voters, like the ones who put her in
Parliament, tend increasingly to be pro-Brexit and nativist. Mrs Cox was a
fervent pro-European.
She had complained to the police of abuse, but
MPs do not receive police protection. This year, British Members of Parliament were
advised to take taxis home, over fears that they could be
attacked by members of the public over the handling of Brexit. "Personally,
I have never felt this level of tension during my time in the House and I am
aware that other colleagues feel the same," wrote the Deputy Speaker in an
email. "Many colleagues have already been subject to widely publicized
abuse and intimidation."
On January 1, the day after the national
elections on December 31, 2018, a mother
of four was gang-raped in the city of Noakhali, Bangladesh, for
voting for the opposition (Daily Star, January 2, 2019).
“They had repeatedly insisted that I should vote
for boat [the symbol of the ruling Awami League] but I cast my ballot for
'sheaf of paddy' [that of the opposition],” she said.
Around a dozen ruling party men armed with sticks
entered her house after midnight, tied up her husband and children, took her
outside and raped her. The woman alleged the rapists were accomplices of Ruhul
Amin, a former member of Char Jubilee Union Parishad.
Her husband said that she had gone to cast her
vote at Char Jubilee-14 Government Primary School centre around 11:00 am on
Sunday. She took the ballot paper from the assistant presiding officer and went
to a booth.
At that time, Ruhul, an Awami League man,
insisted she vote for the “boat”. He allegedly tried to snatch the ballot paper
as she said she would vote for the “sheaf of paddy”. But she put the paper
inside the box.
This made Ruhul furious and he threatened her,
he said.
(In the event, the
government won all the seats in parliament barring eleven, which it graciously
‘lost’. The
consensus was that it could have won more convincingly
for, as we have seen, its popularity seems to surge after acts of thuggery and
murder. However, the electoral outcome was considerably better than the conduct
of Ethiopia’s
ruling party in 2015, when it won every seat in parliament!)
We began this essay with an earlier case of
political hatred, as the reader will recall.
Second, and this is
closely associated with the above, is the absence of the monopoly of violence. In
his lecture “Politics as a Vocation” (1918), the German sociologist Max
Weber defines the state as a “human community that
(successfully) claims the monopoly of the legitimate use of physical force
within a given territory.” In short, under democratic rulers, the state is
missing in Bangladesh (and India as well, where the RSS, the Bajrang Dal, Shiv
Sena and others routinely act outside the state; the use of thugs in politics
is widespread, as depicted in the Hindi movie Vaastav (1999). The
plot can be found here.).
Sheikh Mujib had a
private army (the Jatiyo Rakhi Bahini), his daughter, Sheikh Hasina, has the
Chatra League and Jubo League, her rival, Khaleda Zia, has the Chatra Dal and
Jubo Dal. After the slaughter by the Rakhi Bahini in the early ‘70s, we see
slaughter again after 1990 – more than 80% of all hartals on this land since
1945 occurred after the miraculous year. Hartals require enormous personnel, in
short, a private army. And private armies are inconsistent with the state.
With General Zia
(1977-1981), General Ershad (1983-1990) and General Moeen (2007-2008), the
military possessed the monopoly of legitimate violence. By means of democracy,
it seems, we have reverted to the Hobbesian state of nature. These men may or
may not have had good dispositions, but the situation they were in made for
goodness.
Third, we must recall
that the quality of the electorate determines the quality of the candidate
pool, and ultimately the quality of governments and the rulers. The military rulers of Bangladesh never had to appeal to morally challenged voters.Norman Davies
described German voters in the 1930s as “cannibals” who elected a government of
“cannibals”. The European elite have been vigilant against the return of this
species of voters. In South Asia, the elite, by pandering to the people, have
produced toxic rulers.
When extra-judicial
killings, disappearances, battery of child and student protesters by
student-thugs, allegations of threats to the former Chief Justice’s friend, and
so on, and so forth, increase the
popularity of the government, it can hardly be faulted for a rational course of
action, aimed at maximising votes. After all, it is not Amnesty International
or Human Rights Watch that put the party in power, but the people.
On the campaign trail
in the Philippines, Rodrigo
Duterte, in speaking of an Australian missionary who
had been raped and murdered during a prison riot, lamented that he had not been
first in line to abuse her sexually. He treated allegations of his links to
vigilante killings in the city of Davao, of which he had been mayor, with
pride. And when he promised that he would, as president, dump the corpses of 100,000
gangsters in Manila Bay, the crowd went wild. After he was
elected president of the Philippines, the country’s police killed
at least 40 suspected criminals in the following two months,
more than in the preceding four months combined. A human rights worker, on
condition of anonymity for fear of reprisals, told a newspaper
that Duterte was “our most popular president since Cory Aquino”.
Thaksin Shinawatra,
former prime minister of Thailand, meted out bloody vigilante
justice to alleged drug-runners and to government
opponents in the Muslim and often strife-torn south of the country. In a
shooting spree in 2003, over
2,500 people died in three months, making the prime
minister a hero. The police blamed gang violence; human-rights groups accused
the government of condoning extra-judicial killings by the security forces. And
a panel set up in 2007 by the outgoing junta concluded that over half of those
killed in 2003 had no links to the drugs trade. The panel blamed the violence
on a government “shoot-to-kill” policy based on flawed blacklists. His
popularity was such that it took a military coup to remove him from office.
Yet, his mantle passed easily to his sister.
That the quality of
voters would determine outcome is an observation as old as democracy itself. Thus
we have Plato’s famous lines in The Republic:
“And those who have
been of this little company and have tasted the sweetness and blessedness of
this possession and who have also come to understand the madness of the
multitude sufficiently and seen that there is nothing, if I may say so, sound
or right in any present politics, and that there is no ally with whose aid the
champion of justice could escape destruction, but that he would be as a man who
has fallen among wild beasts, unwilling to share their misdeeds and unable to
hold out singly against the savagery of all, and that he would thus, before he
could in any way benefit his friends or the state, come to an untimely end
without doing any good to himself or others – for all these reasons, I say the
philosopher remains quiet, minds his own affair, and, as it were, standing
aside under the shelter of a wall in a storm of blast of dust and sleet and
seeing others filled full of lawlessness, is content if in any way he may keep
himself free from iniquity and unholy deeds through this life and take his departure
with fair hope, serene and well content when the end comes (496c-e).”
Compare Thucydides:
“Pericles, indeed, by
his rank, ability and known integrity was enabled to exercise an independent
control over the multitude –in short, to lead them instead of being led by
them;...what was nominally a democracy became in his hands government by the
first citizen. With his successors it was different. More on a level with one
another, and each grasping at supremacy, they ended by committing even the
conduct of state affairs to the whims of the multitude (History of the
Peloponnesian War, (trans. Richard Crawley, Chicago: Encyclopaedia Britannica,
Inc., 1952), II-65).”
For Aristotle,
democracy is a perversion of constitutional government: “Of the above-mentioned
forms, the perversions are as follows: of kingship, tyranny; of aristocracy,
oligarchy; of constitutional government, democracy. For tyranny is a kind of
monarchy which has in view the interest of the monarch only; oligarchy has in
view the interest of the wealthy; democracy, of the needy: none of them the
common good of all (Politics, 1279b4-10).” “But when the many administer the
state for the common interest, the government is called by the generic name – a
constitution (1279a36-37).”
Aristotle’s view of
democracy was to have a lasting effect on Europe. According to John Dunn,
democracy was “a form of government which simply did not aim at a common good.
It was a regime of naked group interest, unapologetically devoted to serving
the many at the expense of the wealthier, the better, the more elevated, the
more fastidious or virtuous…. Not only was democracy violent, unstable and
menacing to those who already had wealth, power or pretension, it was,
Aristotle taught many centuries of European speakers to mean, ill-intentioned
and disreputable in itself through and through (Setting the People Free, p
50).”
It is interesting to
note what Aristotle has to say about democracy, the rule of law, and
demagogues. “For in democracies which are subject to the law the best citizens
hold the first place, and there are no demagogues; but where the laws are not
supreme, there demagogues spring up. For the people becomes a monarch, and are
many in one; and the many have the power in their hand, not as individuals, but
collectively…. At all events this sort of democracy, which is now a monarchy,
and no longer under the control of law, seeks to exercise monarchical sway, and
grows into a despot; the flatterer is held in honour; this sort of democracy is
to other democracies what tyranny is to other forms of monarchy. The spirit of
both is the same, and they alike exercise a despotic rule over the better
citizens; the decrees of the one correspond to the edicts of the tyrant; and
the demagogue is to the one what the flatterer is to the other. Both have great
power – the flatterer with the tyrant, the demagogue with democracies of the
kind we are describing. The demagogues make the decrees of the people override
the laws, by referring all things to the popular assembly…. Such a democracy is
fairly open to the objection that it is not a constitution at all; for where
the laws have no authority, there is no constitution (1292a6-32).”
We find an echo of
this in Byron:
I wish men to be free
As much from mobs as kings—from you as me.
We have seen that
democratic practice, such as it is, in South Asia, has been inconsistent with
the promotion of human rights and the rule of law. There is nothing axiomatic
or universal about the latter: they are values, shared or un-shared, with or
without consensus. The question of abortion may be recalled.
It would be tempting
to join Human Rights Watch and Amnesty International in their struggle for
human rights and the rule of law, but it is a fruitless endeavour. Violation
brings popularity, the life-blood of toxic leaders. The followers and the
followed are on the same page.
Besides, there is, as
always, the problem of translation. Words like ‘democracy’ and ‘rights’ must be
translated into the local language. Without going into a detailed analysis, let
us consider the
famous definition offered by Jacob Zuma as president of
South Africa. “You have more rights because you’re a majority; you have less
rights because you’re a minority. That’s how democracy works.” Or take the
equally revealing translation of the word ‘democracy’ made by Turkey’s toxic
president, Recep Tayyip Erdogan, who said that democracy is like a train; you
get off once you have reached your destination.
Words travel; ideas
don’t.
We recall that
democracy had been a pariah world. Today, we glibly pronounce ‘democracy, human
rights and the rule of law’ as somehow entailing each other, a Holy Trinity.
But, as Helen
Rosenblatt, author of The Lost History of Liberalism: From
Ancient Rome to the Twenty-first Century (Princeton: Princeton University
Press, 2018), points out:
“A common mistake we
make today is to use the expression “liberal democracy” unproblematically, as
if “liberalism” and “democracy” go together naturally. Sometimes the terms are
used interchangeably as if they were synonyms. However, for the first one
hundred years of their history, most liberals were hostile to democracy, which
they associated with chaos and mob rule. Certainly, the founders of liberalism
were not democrats. Although he believed in popular sovereignty, Benjamin
Constant insisted that it be limited and advocated stiff property requirements
for voting and office holding. Madame de Staël championed the “government of
the best,” which she distinguished from democracy.
“To Constant, de
Staël, and many other liberals, the French Revolution proved that the public
was utterly unprepared for political rights. People were ignorant, irrational
and prone to violence. Under popular pressure, the rule of law had been
suspended, “enemies of the people” guillotined, and rights trampled upon.
Napoleon’s despotic rule, repeatedly legitimized by plebiscite, only confirmed
the liberals’ apprehensions about democracy.
They watched with horror as demagogues and dictators manipulated voters
by appealing to their lowest instincts. It was obvious to them that the masses
lacked the judgement necessary to know their true interests, and even less
those of their country. Liberals accepted democracy very late and even then
they thought hard about ways to contain it.
They pondered methods to “enlighten” and “educate” democracy and make it
safe.”
Clearly, there is a
leadership role here for the elite, one that the South Asian elite is incapable
of fulfilling, not having got over their colonial hangover. The post-war
European elite have shown a sense of responsibility forged in the furnace of
history.
In Charles Taylor’s
prophetic words, “European societies have tended to follow along behind their
elite cultures more than American, we said above. But this effect is magnified
at the “European” level, where the running has been entirely made by these
elites - with consequences which have emerged recently in referenda in various
states on the Continent (A Secular Age, p 831, n 46).”
We have seen Louis
Michel’s heroic manoeuvring to side line the Freedom Party, which had Neo-Nazi
roots. However, in 2017, the
Austrian People’s Party (OVP) and the Austrian Freedom Party (FPO)
formed a coalition government with hardly a susurrus from Europe. When the two
last formed a government, back in 2000, the news provoked diplomatic sanctions:
visits and meetings were cancelled. The Freedom Party has redefined the
outgroup as Islam in lieu of their former anti-Semitism (recognising Jerusalem
as Israel’s capital long before Donald Trump).
The refugee crisis
was, in the argot of psychiatrists, the ‘trigger’ that drove voters into the
arms of far-right xenophobes. The sudden upswell of an outgroup, alien in
language and religion (though not in Britain, in the latter case), made a
salience for the ingroup: nationalist feeling re-emerged. This has strained the
compact between the cosmopolitan elite and an increasingly nationalist society.
In 2013 the Alternative
for Germany (AfD) fell short of the 5% of votes needed to enter parliament. The
party had been founded to oppose EU bail-outs of debt-stricken countries like
Greece, which many Germans saw as a transfer from industrious German taxpayers
to feckless Greeks. The AfD was then transformed as nationalists took it over
and began to rail against immigrants and Islam – an outgroup that afforded
greater scope for hostility. Unsurprisingly, the AfD won 13% of the vote in
2017, making it the third-biggest force in parliament, causing some disquiet.
Although the AfD’s
agenda is not remotely like that of the Third Reich (people seen giving Nazi
salutes have “nothing to do with our party”, said Beatrix von Storch, its
deputy leader), a
new paper finds an uncomfortable overlap between the
parts of Germany that support the AfD and those that voted for the Nazis in
1933.
German expellees after
the war flocked to the north, where the Nazis had done well, thus upsetting
pre-war demographics. In the south-west, these were preserved. It is only in
areas where pre-war demographics still persist that electoral maps show strong
echoes of the past. Parts of the south-west that backed the Nazis in 1933 also
embraced the AfD, and those that shunned Hitler rejected it. Overall, the
paper’s authors found that among municipalities with average far-right support
but few expellees, a 1% increase in the Nazis’ vote share in 1933 was
associated with an extra 0.3-0.5% gain for the AfD from 2013-17. The Nazis are
not coming back, but nationalism has deep roots.
Matteo Salvini, the
head of the Northern League, a populist party that forms part of Italy’s governing
coalition, has a ready explanation for the global rise of movements like his.
“It is a common factor,” he says. “The confrontation of the people versus the
elite.”
Scholars
agree. Since 1999 the University of North Carolina at
Chapel Hill has surveyed political scientists about European parties’ policy
positions and rhetoric, yielding ideological ratings for each party on various
issues. The attribute most correlated with gaining votes since 2014 has been
criticism of elites.
“The educated,
multilingual cosmopolitan elite of Europe grew weaker,” writes the historian Norman
Davies of the era before the Great War, “the
half-educated national masses, who thought of themselves only as Frenchmen,
Germans, English or Russians, grew stronger.”
The repression of
nationalism by the European elite has been a Herculean effort at cleansing the
Augean stables. Nationalism is a formidable religion, founded on the atavistic
human need for ingroup-outgroup hatred, and requiring little or no education,
its doctrinal dimension being well-nigh a black hole. Any enterprise built on
rational foundations, such as the European Union, and not resting on a visceral
myth, will be sorely tested by hoary impulses to the contrary. One can only
hope (one is almost tempted to say, pray) for its future.
Whatever may be the
future of the European Union, it is an undeniable fact that in certain
‘suitable’ situations, human behaviour will become pathological. “The banality
of evil” is one of the most insightful expressions to have come out of our
experience of evil.
Toxic leaders do not
occur only in politics. They occur in business and non-profits as well, where
leaders do not have the coercive power of police, spies and thugs at their
disposal. One of the most toxic leaders in history (and one was much admired by
Machiavelli) was the Pope - until one of his followers got up the guts to
revolt. More recently, it took nearly fifty years for lay members of the
Catholic Church in Boston to call for the ouster of toxic religious leaders
involved in the sexual abuse of hundreds of young parishioners (The Allure of
Toxic Leaders, p 126).
Leadership is not an
action, but an interaction. People seem often to prefer toxic to benign leaders. Lippman-Blumen observes: “During
their heyday, Enron’s Kenneth Lay and Jeffrey Skilling, WorldCom’s Bernard
Ebbers, ImClone’s Samuel Waksal, Tyco International’s L. Dennis Kozlowski,
Sunbeam’s Al Dunlap, HealthSouth’s Richard Crushy, Adolf Hitler, Boston’s Roman
Catholic Cardinal Bernard Law, TV
evangelist James Bakker, and Texas Tech basketball coach Bobby Knight, for
starters, enjoyed – and many still enjoy – enthusiastic support from followers
(p 4).”
To this illustrious
list may be added such luminaries as Mao Zedong, Pol Pot, Robert Mugabe, Sheikh
Mujibur Rahman, Zulfiquar Ali Bhutto, Indira Gandhi, Khaleda Zia, Sheikh Hasina,
Aung San Suu Kyi, Hugo Chavez, Nicolas Maduro, Recep Tayyip Erdogan….
An example of toxic followers in the corporate world can be
given. When a jury convicted Michael R. Milken, the ‘junk bond king’ of
investment firm Drexel Burnham Lambert, former DBL employees arrived on Phil
Donohue’s TV show. Unanimously, the still unemployed stockbrokers and
administrative assistants spoke glowingly of their former boss, despite the
fact that Milken’s illegal actions led to the closure of the firm and the loss
of their jobs (p 4).
On the fiftieth
anniversary of the Cultural Revolution in China, the Communist Party played it
down, declaring it a “disaster”. Yet Maoists
maintain that the Cultural Revolution was a good idea:
China needed one to prevent the kind of slide towards capitalism that the country
was now suffering. In May Maoist websites in China published photographs of a
meeting of Mao-lovers in Xi’an, the capital of Shaanxi province. “Long Live the
Great Proletarian Cultural Revolution” proclaimed a red banner along one side
of the room, where more than 50 people sat in rows before a large portrait of
Mao.
Do not look for saints
among formal leaders, warns Lipman-Blumen. Saints rarely seek elected or
appointed office. She adds that “followers knowingly tolerate, seldom unseat,
frequently prefer, and sometimes even creates toxic leaders (p 5).”
The best example of a
created toxic leader must be Aung San Suu Kyi. A long-time military prisoner in
Burma (Myanmar), she received the Nobel Peace Prize for her heroic
determination to bring democracy. However, when hundreds of thousands of
Rohingya refugees streamed out of Rakhine state in south-east Burma to
Bangladesh, Ms. Suu Kyi (who rules as the only ‘state councillor’, remained
shtum. The UN said Myanmar’s
treatment of the Rohingya was tantamount to “ethnic
cleansing”.
Hatred of the Rohingya
is the one thing that unites almost everyone in Myanmar, said another diplomat:
“The extremist Buddhists, the masses, the army, and even the NLD [National
League for Democracy, Ms. Suu Kyi’s party].” Even somebody of her charisma
cannot stand up to her own ingroup against an outgroup perceived as alien. Nyan
Win, a party spokesman and Aung San Suu Kyi’s personal lawyer, voiced the views
of many in Myanmar when he told Radio Free Asia: “I think everyone knows the
Bengali. There are no facial features like Bengalis’ in our Myanmar, nowhere in
the country.” The Rohingya are regarded as illegal infiltrators from
Bangladesh.
“If the political
price of your ascension to the highest office in Myanmar is your silence, the
price is surely too steep,” the South African social rights activist and fellow
Nobel peace prize winner Desmond Tutu wrote.
When she finally broke
her silence, her speech was described by Amnesty
International as a “mix of untruths and victim-blaming”.
She found herself at
the centre of global ire. Her face again adorns placards at protests across the
globe but this time the chants are angry. An attempt to revoke her Nobel peace
prize has garnered hundreds of thousands of signatures.
More recently, one of South Korea’s largest human rights
groups said it will strip Myanmar's de facto leader Aung San Suu Kyi of its
2004 Gwangju prize because of her "indifference" to the atrocities
against the Rohingya minority.
Amartya
Sen famously proclaimed that “A country does not have
to be deemed fit for democracy; rather, it has to become fit through democracy.”
Without going into the question of whether democracy or epistocracy is to be preferred
(the latter being Plato and Brennan’s choice), let us ask a more humdrum
question: after how many murders and rapes does a country become ‘fit for
democracy through democracy’?
When society has a
goal in the future, beyond the individual today, no crime is gruesome enough to
discredit the outcome. Twentieth-century aspirations went along these lines,
but it was hoped that in this century the lessons will have been well-learned.
When we see the dead
bodies on the highway, some charred, others mutilated, what epitaph will we
write for them?
“In a way, you could
say, they died for democracy.”